Shifting
China’s
Export towards the Domestic Market
By
Henry C. K. Liu
Part I: Breaking Free
from Dollar Hegemony
Part II: Developing China with Sovereign Credit
This article appeared in AToL
on September 4, 2008
The two key factors preventing the use of sovereign credit
to finance sustainable development of the domestic sector of the
Chinese economy
are China’s
high export dependency operating under dollar hegemony and the
ill-advised blanket
privatization of the public sector.
The term "privatization" is generally defined as
any process aimed at shifting government functions and
responsibilities, in
whole or in part, to the profit-driven private sector. Privatization of
government responsibilities is touted by both conservatives and
neoliberals as the remedy
for
government inefficiency and corruption. Yet the record shows that both
public
and private sectors, given the opportunity, have shown equally high
propensity
to become inefficient, corrupt and unethical, each in its own way.
In the shadow of the 1930s Great Depression and chastened by the
horror of global modern war, Western societies in the 20th
century sought to redefine social provision and the notion of public
good.
There was renewed concern with the rights of citizenship and
entitlement to
basic services (health care, education, public housing, subsidized mass
transport and unemployment insurance) as part of a “social wage”. These
programs were purposely removed from the pressure of the market, to be
funded
by general taxation at progressive rates for the benefit of all. The
strength
of the welfare state varied from one country to another. It had its
weakest
foothold in the United States.
But the rationale was the same: social cohesion and economic progress
were
furthered by a shared sense of community. Forty years later ideology
took an
about-face. The welfare state came under attack and nowhere more so
than in Britain,
one of the countries where it was most advanced, led by Margaret
Thatcher.
Ronald Reagan jumped on the reactionary train in the US. See my February 12, 2005 AToL article: The
Privatization
Wave
Privatization of the public sector, generally taking the
form of sale or lease of public assets or property rights to private
interests,
is a path toward failed state status even for a sovereign state
with a capitalist
market economy. By definition the public sector exists because there
are
elements of the economy that the private sector cannot handle
efficiently
without externalizing some major costs to the economy as a whole.
Operationally, privatization of the public sector generally takes
the path of corporatization of state-owned enterprises by offering
shares for
sale in the capital market to those who have access to money. This
approach presents
ideological as well as practical problems for a socialist society such
as China’s,
in transition towards a socialist market economy. In a socialist
economy,
state-owned-enterprises (SOEs) are owned collectively by all the
people.
Ideally, everyone enjoys all the consumable wealth he/she needs and no
one
needs to personally worry about savings for rainy days as excess wealth
to
invest. Savings in a socialist society are done collectively with the
need to
save socialized.
Privatization of SOEs that operate in the public sector through
corporatization via initial public offerings of shares raises issues of
equity
and social justice, aside from the fact that it drains private capital
unnecessarily from the part of the private sector that otherwise serves
a
legitimate economic function. This drain of private capital causes
interest
rates in the private sector to rise needlessly and reduces the
efficiency of
the entire economy.
Without an institutional framework in place to transfer
state-owned property fairly to all members of the owning public with
low
transaction costs, the initial uneven private allocation of state-owned
property and the lack of fluidity in secondary markets can and often do
undermine social justice and welfare by exacerbating wealth and income
inequality. A practical problem for socialist countries such as China
is from whence would the potential
domestic
buyers with money come? Surely not from members of the proletariat
class who by
definition have no money for private investment, not even from latent
capitalists
since they were not allowed to exist before the age of reform toward
market
economy. Domestic buyers then must come from a small circle who are in
a
position to manipulated finances to gain access to bank loans
collateralized by
the very shares they intent to buy. Foreign buyers, albeit now still
limited in
the amount they can purchase, end up buying the best
state-owned-enterprises at
bargain prices in a buyer’s market. The problem has been the lightning
rod of
public complaint in past decade.
Some Eastern European transitional economies have used
complicated voucher schemes in which public assets could be distributed
broadly
among private citizens and collectively-owned institutions with
legitimate
claims on them. Voucher holders could then trade these new instruments
of
ownership at market value as pseudo-stocks of public asset being
privatized.
Such voucher systems inevitably suffer from high transaction costs and
other
market inefficiencies caused by the unmanageably large number of
individual
voucher recipients, uneven market information, and the difficulties in
organizing and regulating a fair market.
The net result has been to provide legal but unfair
opportunities for unsavory and manipulative speculators, often
foreigners
with sophisticate experience and expertise in financial engineering, to
buy
up the
dispersed vouchers at high discount and use them to subsequently
acquire
control of the privatized SOEs on the cheap. Such privatization
processes are
vivid examples of free market fairness not adding up to economic
justice.
Many East European states transitioning from socialist
economy to market economy thus rely on auction mechanisms to both value
and
privatize state-owned property. Auctions can better determine the fair
market
price of assets based upon a number of factors: earning history and
future potential,
industry trends, auction rules and process, and availability and cost
of money.
Restructuring of the entity before it is suitable for sale is usually
necessary
before an auction can proceed.
External factors affecting market value involve anticipated
post-privatization
contractual relationship with governmental customers, the stage of
privatization within the economy, potential competitors and market competition environment, and the
degree of continuing government control of and regulation on the
privatized
entity, the industry and the private sector generally.
The auction process itself can influence market values by
the way the state packages a SOE or parts of it for sale. Macroeconomic
policies also affect enterprise market value. Bidding qualifications
such as
restricting auctions to buyers that meet eligibility qualifications set
by the
state can also affect market value. Such qualifying restriction can
include buyer
citizenship and other non-financial requirements to preserve
socio-economic
justice.
Pre-auction restructuring efforts that require management
changes, layoffs, debt absorption, efficiency improvement measures,
investment
priorities, bridge capital and loans and adjustment in contracts with
other
stat-owned enterprises placed prior to the auction can raise
transaction cost
and lower the transaction value. For example, one determinant in
pricing is the
prospect of unionization of labor and workers’ right to strike against
a
private corporation.
Aside from the issue of social justice, transitional economies need to
weigh the
social cost of privatization because a privatized entity often gains
operational efficiency by externalizing part of its cost to society at
large.
Also, state-owned-enterprises are mistakenly viewed in neo-liberal
circles as inevitably
failing to operate efficiently as a result of nebulous property rights,
uneconomic pricing due to government subsidy and intervention in
management.
This view leads reformers to seek misguided blanket privatization as a
cure all
to stimulate more growth.
SOEs do need reform to improve their performance as a
category, but privatization is not the answer. More to the point is to
allow
SOE salaries and wages to rise to levels competitive with private
companies to
retain and attract talent, to introduce meritocracy in management and
to
provide superior enterprise-financed training and education for career
advancement. Also, SOE efficiency will improve if social benefits, such
as
health care, employee housing, children education, etc., are not
provided by
each enterprise separately but outsourced to special function SOEs that
can
better capture economy of scale.
Ownership and management have been separate in market
economies for more than a century. In fact the separation is recognized
as the
most significant factor in the growth of free market capitalism. Also, profit-based pricing often adds
aggregate inflationary pressure to the economy as a whole while
producing
profit only to individual units to be distributed to shareholders.
Subsidized
food prices are a clear example of this dilemma. Further, government
bailout of
failed private enterprises is commonplace in free market capitalism.
In the US
where free market capitalism operates as a religious faith and the
private
sector dominates the economy, glaring examples of failed enterprises
emerge
repeatedly whenever government regulation fails. The most serious giant
corporate failures invariably require government bailout to prevent
systemic
damage to the economy. This is known as the “too big to fail” syndrome.
The
most recent examples in the finance sector are Fannie Mae and Freddie
Mac, Bear
Stearns, Countrywide and IndyMac. In recent history, the list of failed
companies included Drexel Burnham & Lambert, Enron, WorldCom,
Global
Crossing, Pan Am Airline, Macy’s, Delphi Auto Parts, Continental
Illinois National Bank and Trust Company and numerous
other bankruptcies. Penn Central filed for bankruptcy and its passenger
lines
were nationalized as Amtrak in 1971 and its freight traffic
nationalized as
Conrail in 1976. Chrysler required a $1.5 billion government guaranteed
loan in
1979 to avoid bankruptcy.
The case of Enron illustrates the systemic fraud on a large
scale that could occur in an under-regulated market with major banks as
eager
participants in dubious financial manipulation. In 1985, taking
advantage of a
weakened antitrust regime, Enron was formed from a merger of Houston
Natural
Gas and InterNorth Gas of Omaha, Nebraska. By 2000, Enron had grown
into the
largest natural gas merchant in North America,
eventually branching out from a pipeline company into a major trader of
energy,
electricity and other commodities such as water, coal and steel. The
company
attracted eager investors and its stocks rose phenomenally.
Unfortunately, Enron’s spectacular success came from its
strategy of fraudulently manipulating its financials to achieve
unsupported
market value for its stock, resulting in the ultimate and inevitable
collapse
of the company as the fantasy bubble based on fraud burst and public
trust in
it evaporated.
A more recent example of widespread fraud is the promotion
and marketing of auction rate securities (ARS), debt instruments with
long
nominal maturities for which the interest rate is regularly reset
through a
Dutch auction by bidding investors betting on money market movements.
Major
banks and brokerage houses market ARS as safe and liquid instruments,
almost
the equivalent of cash, to institutional investors, including pension
funds,
and charities, individuals, and small businesses, by promising to be
bidders of
last resort. But in early 2008, as the credit crisis that began in
August 2007
caused the failure of up to 80% of the ARS market, the four largest
investment
banks which normally make a market in these securities (Citigroup, UBS,
Morgan
Stanley and Merrill Lynch) declined to act as bidders of last resort,
as they
had promised to do, causing losses to investors.
On August 1, 2008,
New York State Attorney General Andrew Cuomo notified Citigroup of his
intent
to file charges over alleged Citigroup misrepresentation in the sale of
troubled auction-rate securities as safe instruments. Investigators
also
accused Citigroup of illegally destroying relevant documents.
A week later, on August 7, in response to state and federal
regulators charges, Citigroup was reported as having agreed in
principle to
settle the auction rate securities charges by buying back about $7.3
billion of
auction-rate securities it sold to charity organizations, individual
investors,
and small businesses. The agreement also calls for Citigroup to use
“best
efforts” to make all of the US$12 billion auction-rate securities it
sold to
institutional investors, including retirement plans, liquid by the end
of 2009.
The settlement allowed Citigroup to avoid admitting or denying claims
that it
fraudulently sold auction-rate securities as safe, liquid investments.
On the same day, a few hours after the Citigroup settlement
announcement, Merrill Lynch announced that effective January 15, 2009, and
through January 15, 2010,
it will offer to
buy back at par auction rate securities sold by it to retail clients.
Merrill’s
action provided critically needed liquidity for more than 30,000
investor
clients who hold municipal, closed-end funds and student loan auction
rate
securities. Under the plan, retail clients of Merrill would have a
year-long
option in which to sell back to Merrill the auction rate securities
they bought
at face value should the market value fall below that.
There is also the issue of the settlement’s focus on points
of sale rather than on the underwriting institutions which broke their
promise
of making markets for the auctions, which is a much larger problem than
the
settlement had so far covered. Also the liquidity provided by the Fed
through
its discount window is accessible only to the large national investment
banks
but not to regional brokerage firms which acted as the large investment
banks’
agents. Further, the settlement is not global in the sense that
investors who
bought ARS from regional firms that were not included in the settlement
are not
offered any buybacks. There was also a
full disclosure issue in that when the auction market first began to
crack, not
all potential buyers were in possession of the critical information
that the
market might seize up or they would not have bought ARS if they had
known.
The State Attorney’s office is also probing the relationship
between Fidelity Investments, the nation’s largest mutual fund manager
and
Goldman Sachs on the sale of ARS’s. Most of the SAS’s sold by Fidelity
was
underwritten by Goldman. There was a question of conflict of interest
in terms
of undue incentive to sell Goldman underwritten instruments to Fidelity
retail
customers because Fidelity was protecting its other lucrative services
from
Goldman, including other Goldman underwriting of private offerings of
instruments Fidelity developed for accredited investors. In short, this
is
crony capitalism at work. What is a amazing is that this practice has
been
going on for years, yet it takes until now before those in charge of
fair and
equitable market to catch on. Better late than never, and it could have
been
never if a crisis had not broken out.
In the same month, the Securities Exchange Commission’s
Division of Enforcement engaged in preliminary settlements with several
of the
larger broker-dealers including Citigroup, JPMorgan Chase, Merrill
Lynch,
Morgan Stanley and UBS. The proposed settlement calls for these
broker-dealers
to repurchase outstanding ARS from their individual investors. Still
the ARS
market has remained under seizure as public trust in the market
evaporated. Goldman may be added to the
list before long.
According to a new study by Greenwich Associates released on August 15, 2008,
nearly 60% of the 146 hedge
funds, banks and long-only managers surveyed say they expect to see
another
major financial services firm collapse within the next six months as a
result
of the ongoing credit crisis, and another 15% think it will happen in
six to 12
months. Counterparty risk in credit-default swaps is shaping up as a
serious
threat to global financial markets. Outstanding credit default swaps is
around
$45 trillion, which is 3 times larger than US GDP of $15 trillion and
300 times
larger than the Bush relief plan of $150 billion. See my January 26, 2008 article in
AToL: THE ROAD TO HYPERINFLATION:
Fed
helpless in its own crisis.
Harvard macroeconomic professor Kenneth
Rogoff, former IMF chief economist, warned publicly in August, 2008
that the worst
of the global financial crisis is yet to come and a large US bank will fail in the next few months as the world’s
biggest
economy hits further troubles. Indications are mounting that public
trust in
free market capitalism appears to be in shorter supply with every
passing week.
The Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation has warned
repeatedly with increasing urgency that the outlook for distressed
banks is bad
and getting worse as a result of toxic home martgages spreading
throughout the
entire financial sector. By June 2008, the agency’s Q2 report showed
the number
of bad loans having ballooned to its highest level since 1985, which
led to the
1987 crash. In Q2 2008, bank profits plunges 86% between April and June
from
$36.8 billion to $4.96 billion. The agency raised the number of problem
banks
on its list to 117, the highest since 2003. The number was 90 at the
end of Q1,
2008, already bad enough.
More new tidal waves of credit crunches are approaching US
and European banks as these institutions face imminent maturity of
massive
amount of floating-rate notes that the banks took on four years earlier
to
borrow money to finance their loose lending. The first wave will hit in
September 2008, when banks must pay off $95 billion of matured notes.
By the end
of 2009, some $787 billion notes will have come due, 43% more than in
the
previous 16 months. This will drive up interest rates in all maturities
even if
the Fed keeps its overnight Fed funds rate target unchanged at 2%. A
year ago
in July 2007, before the current credit crisis broke out, the spread
between
bank floating rate notes and LIBOR (London
Interbank Offer Rate – the rate banks
agree to lend to each
other) was only 0.2%. In August 2008, the spread has gone up ten times
to a
full two percentage points for some banks. The commercial paper market
seizure
and the collapse of SIVs, which had been the main buyer of bank
floating notes,
exacerbated the problem for banks. See my AToL series: Pathology
of
Debt.
Choice for China
Is this the con game China
wants to emulate by privatizing her public sector and opening up her
financial
sector to predatory global capital to allow the few to rob the many? It would be a policy of letting the fox into
the chicken coop. Is the Communist Party of China willing to lead the
Chinese
people to the slaughter house of finance capitalism, at a time when
even the US
is beset with neo-populist clamoring for a return to extensive
government
intervention in, and tight regulation on iniquitous abuses in the
private
sector? It is ironic that Hong Kong, the poster
child of US
free market
apologists, has to repeatedly beg its socialist kin on the Mainland to
give it
preferential subsidy whenever it hits a bump in its supposedly
productive free
market. Is the Communist Party of China willing to betray the sacred
trust of
the masses in China
to stray from unshakable faith and confidence in socialism, merely to
be a
belated “stakeholder” in an exploitative economic system that even the
masses
in the US
are
beginning to reject? Is China
prepared to gamble away the public trust in the Communist Party earned
with the
blood of millions of revolutionary martyrs, to enter the dangerous
minefields
of deregulated markets when US
public trust in unregulated free markets is evaporating faster than
morning
dew?
Free Market Losing Public
Trust
Public trust has been recognized as critical to a vibrant capitalist
market economy ever since the 12th century when the first brokers
traded
private debt and government securities in France.
Unofficial share markets blossomed across urbanized Europe
throughout the 1600s when brokers would meet outdoors or in coffee
houses to
make trades. The emergence of stock markets in cities contributed
directly to the
rise of capitalism by forming purposeful capital from the dispersed
wealth held
by the public at large.
Stock markets, similar to all other free markets, require
government regulation to remain free. This is the socialist component
in all
markets. Well regulated capitalist markets share similarity in
operation with
socialist markets. It is ironic that the US
is blaming China
for unsafe imports. Many policymakers in China
have been misled by US
neoliberal propaganda that free markets mean no government regulation
and that
somehow unsafe products will be screened out by market forces. In
reality,
public trust in society springs from the foundation of trust in an
engaged and
caring sovereign government protecting the interest and welfare of all
the people.
Free market is an arena that operates with the principle of caveat
emptor.
The distinguishing characteristic between capitalism and
socialism is the ownership pattern of the means of production. Free
market
capitalism operates through the joint stock company for the benefit of
shareholders while socialist economies operate through state-own and
collectively-owned enterprises in control of the means of production
for the
benefit of the general population. Enlightened free marketers
grudgingly
acknowledge corporate responsibility to the public, but always only if
it does
not hamper fiduciary responsibility to shareholders. Automakers’
attitude to
car safety is a clear example. Recalls within legal limits are decided
on the
cost of negligent litigation. A safety recall program of $100 per car
covering
a million cars will be launched only if the potential law suit exposure
exceeds
$100 million, unless criminal liability overrides the financial
calculation.
Both free market capitalism and planned socialist economies
are subject to fraud and abuse, albeit through different loopholes.
Capitalist
free markets tend to allow corporate externalization of costs to the
general
economy while privatizing the gains. On the other extremist socialist
economies
tend to place on unit enterprises social costs burdens beyond the
financial
capacity of individual enterprises, causing them to become inefficient
or
failed enterprises. Operationally, the difference lies in the attitude
and
reliance on the extent of government initiative on protection of the
general
public.
Joint Stock Companies
and Colonialism
Joint stock companies are born in the manger of stock
exchanges. The Amsterdam Stock Exchange, created in 1602, was the first
official stock exchange when it began trading shares of the Vereenigde
Oost-Indische Compagnie (VOC or United East Indies Company in
English). It
was the first joint stock company shares ever issued and the
predecessor of the
Dutch East India Company.
The parliament of the Dutch Republic
(1581-1795) granted VOC a
21-year monopoly through a sovereign charter to establish trading
colonies in Asia.
VOC was the first transnational corporation in history. Stock-issuing
transnational companies had since been closely connected to the birth
of
colonialism which took the form of economic conquest of foreign lands
through
capitalist expansion backed by political/military power. It formed the
basis of
Lenin’s observation that imperialism is the highest stage of
capitalism. Today,
modern transnational corporations continue to be linked to
neo-colonialism
backed by neo-imperialist government policies in the name of globalized
free
market fundamentalism.
Is this the game China,
with
a government born of revolutionary liberation, wants to emulate?
Throughout her
long history, China
had trade with the known world for common benefit. But Chinese history
never
included any age of expansionist economic imperialism. When Chinese
mariner
Cheng He (1371-1433) sailed the oceans in 1401 in a ship three times
the size of Columbus’,
he did not found any colonies as Columbus
and his European followers
did. Cheng He reached lands in South and Southeast Asia,
the Persian Gulf and Africa.
Gavin Menzies claims that Cheng He’s fleet went on to reach the New
World,
landing on islands off the Florida coast more than half a century
before Columbus.
Throughout his travels, Zheng He liberally presented his hosts with
Chinese
gifts of silk, porcelain, tea, paper and other unique goods from
Chinese
civilization. In return, he received native presents from his hosts,
including
African zebras and giraffes that were brought back to fill Ming dynasty
imperial game reserves. Zheng He and his sizable entourage paid
respects to
local deities and customs and adopted Islam personally. In Ceylon,
Cheng He erected a three-religion monument honoring Buddha, Allah and
Vishnu.
The use of military force was limited to policing pirates, never on the
natives on the lands Zheng He visited.
Such is the trading model China
should revive in the 21th century, not helping to perpetuate
exploitative Western
globalization facing self-destruct. Chinese neoliberal pundits of today
who
mindless
declare globalization an irreversible trend of world civilization
are only
half right. A new trade globalization
is waiting to burst
out
under enlighten leadership from China, the world’s most populous nation
and soon
to be the largest economy. This new globalized trade will have to
truly benefit all participants without the tyranny of
offshore transnational capital denominated in fiat currency like the
dollar, and that
benefiting only shareholders of transnational corporations. Trade should be conducted to enrich the lives of all
participants, not to reap monetized profits by forcing the weak
participants into perpetual poverty. That is not trade, but
imperialism.
The Role of Sovereign
Charters in Commerce
In England,
sovereign charters historically came in the form of royal
charters granted by the monarch on advice of the Privy
Council, to legitimize incorporated bodies, such as cities, companies,
universities, charities or such, for the betterment of the entire
kingdom. A royal
charter
is a kind of letters patent, a legal instrument in the form of an open
letter
issued by the sovereign, granting an office, right, monopoly, title, or
status
to a legal person such as an individual of merit or a corporation,
implicitly
to advance the interests of the state.
In medieval feudal Europe, cities
were the only place where markets could legally exist to conduct
commerce, and
royal charters were the only way to establish a city independent of
feudal
estates. The year a city was chartered is considered the year the city
was
“founded”, irrespective of whether there was settlement there before.
Chartered
cities were under the protection of the sovereign, exempt from feudal
estate
laws. Cities were locations where feudal estates could interact
commercially as
equals. Producers of different goods could not sell to each other
directly
within or beyond their respective feudal estates, as all assets within
the
estate were the property of the feudal lord. Government
authority over, and supervision of
commerce, have existed
from the very beginning of government in history. That government
should stay out of commerce is barbaric notion.
Producers were allowed by law to bring their surplus goods
to market only at designated locations in chartered cities and at
scheduled
times to sell them for money issued by the ruling sovereign who alone
command
the power of seigniorage. Seigniorage
produces monetary revenue for a sovereign when the created money has a
higher
face value than the intrinsic cost of producing it.
A royal charter can also create and grant special status and
power to an incorporated body, such as the power to tax and to maintain
a
private security force and self-government over territories under its
control.
It is an exercise of the royal prerogative in a monarchy and a
sovereign
prerogative in a republic. A trading monopoly granted by British royal
charter
between the 17th and 19th centuries routinely
possessed
extraterritorial governmental powers in the colonies.
Historically, a royal charter was the only way in which an
incorporated body could be formed in a monarchy. In essence, an
incorporated
entity is a limited collective enterprise. Other means such as the
registration
of a limited company are available in modern times via the commercial
legal
regime, which still involve the granting of sovereign prerogative by a
sovereign state to entitle it to come under the protection of the
state. Among
the historical bodies formed by British royal charter were the British
East
India Company, the Hudson Bay Company, the Peninsular and Oriental
Steam
Navigation Company (P&O), the British South African Company and the
13
American colonies.
To facilitate the achievement of its financial goals, the
VOC was granted by parliament of the Republic of the United Netherlands
quasi-governmental powers on foreign soil, including the power and
ability to
wage war on the native peoples and governments, negotiate treaties,
issue
money,
and establish colonies with laws independent of the homeland legal
regime. This
was the beginning of modern imperialism which is the conquering of
foreign
markets via extraterritorial property rights backed by the threat or
use of
force. Transnational banks were and still are all founded by sovereign
charters. This fact underscores that international trade is a political
extension of sovereign states. This will remain true as long as there
is a world order of sovereign states.
VOC was profitable enough to pay 18% dividend annually
uninterrupted for almost two centuries until its quasi-government power
was
interrupted in 1795 with the fall of Republic of the United Netherlands
which
had been allied with conservative Austrian and British interests. The succeeding Batavian Republic,
backed by the populist French First Republic, nationalized VOC assets and
assumed all outstanding debt of the bankrupt VOC, making its profits
payable to
the state as representatives of all the people, instead of just
shareholders.
The name was changed from United East Indies Company to
Dutch East Indies Company. VOC territories then became the Dutch
East Indies, a colony owned and administered by the Dutch
state.
It was expanded over the course of the 19th century to include the
whole of the
Indonesian archipelago. Under the decolonization policies of the
victorious
Allies at the end of WWII, the Dutch East Indies
became
the independent nation of Indonesia
with 222 million people as the world’s fourth most populous country and
the
most populous Muslim-majority nation. Membership
in spranational institutions such as the World Trade Organiztion, the
International Monetary Frnd and the Bank of International Settlements
is only treaty obligations assumed by soverign states.
Britain
immediately followed the Dutch example of expanding colonialism through
a joint
stock company. The British East India
Trading Company had been granted a royal charter by Elisabeth I
on December 31, 1600,
two years before
the founding of VOC, with the intention of bestowing upon it favorable
trade
privileges with India.
The company was a collective enterprise of London
private businessmen who banded together to make money importing spices
from South
Asia. The royal charter granted the newly created company a
21-year monopoly on all British trade in the East Indies.
The Company through private placement quickly transformed from a
private
commercial trading venture to one that virtually ruled India and other
Asian
colonies as an imperialist overlord as it acquired auxiliary
governmental and
military capability. But its shares were not publicly traded until
after the
founding of the London
stock
exchange in 1801. Thereafter, the corporate structure of the British
East India Company became a classic model of a successful publicly
traded
joint
stock company. Many innovative organizational features, such as
reliance of a
network of highly compensated agents, known as compradors, to
efficiently
exploit chaotic markets, were later copied by modern transnational
corporations. The comprador system reduced capital levels for the
company while
spread the risk away from the company. Much of the dirty exploitation
was
carried out by comprador agents while top management at company
headquarter
stayed above it all by comforting itself with having played fair
according to
the high-sounding principles of capitalism,
For centuries, spice trade with the East Indies
relied on land routes across Asia and the Middle
East, but by the sixteenth century, the superior shipping
technology of the Portuguese permitted Europeans to cut out Arabic
intermediaries
to make far greater profits. The Spanish and Portuguese had a monopoly
of the East Indies spice trade until
destruction of the Spanish Armada in
1588, which permitted the British and Dutch to control this lucrative
trade.
Yet British East India Company policies in Bengal
were responsible for failing to prevent the Bengal
famine of 1770 which left a third of the native population of 30
million dead
from starvation. As a trading entity owned and run by a foreign race,
the
Company’s mandate was to maximize profit by exploiting its chartered
right to
impose land tax over its jurisdiction and trade tariffs on imports.
Land tax in Bengal
was raised five folds from 10% to 50% of the
estimated value of the agricultural produce on all land in territory
control by
the Company, including land not directly owned by the Company.
Land tax was the key devise of the British colonial
authorities of all its colonies to make the natives productive in
monetary
terms. Native farmers and rangers were compelled to produce more than
their
families needed for consumption and to sell the surplus in the market
for money
issued by the Company to pay land taxes. Most of the tax revenue did
not stay
in India
or
other colonies for local development. It flowed to England
as dividends for British shareholders. All investments in India,
and other colonies were directed toward raising trade profit for the
Company,
rather than to improve the welfare of the natives. As the Bengal
famine approached its most severe stage in April of 1770, the Company
announced
a further increase of the land tax to 60% of potential production
value.
The Company forbade the “hoarding” of rice at good harvest
so that it could maximize profit from low prices it paid growers due to
a supply glut, thus prevented traders and dealers
from
holding reserves for poor harvest to feed the native population during
lean
periods. It also paid farmers to plant opium and tea cash crops instead
of rice
to increase company profit. The tea that was dumped into the harbor by
members
of the
Boston Tea Party in the American Revolution in 1773 was British East
India
Company property. American colonists were protesting the British East
India
Company’s monopoly over tea exports to the colonies. By the time of the
famine,
full monopoly in grain trading had been firmly established in India
by the Company and its agents. The Company had no plan for dealing with
the
grain shortage besides measures to assure food supply for British
executives
and their native employees. Globally, company profit doubled in the
decade of
the famine.
The privileged monopoly of the Company was criticized by
Adam Smith, advocate of free trade, Edmund Burke, apologist for
American
secessionism yet conservative critic of the French Revolution, and
British home
merchants locked out of the lucrative Asia
trade, who
protested the Company’s administrative abuses and monopolistic
ineptitude. In
1833, Parliament declined to extend the monopoly of the British East
India
Company on trade between Britain
and China.
Jardine, Matheson and Company took advantage of this open market
opportunity to
transform itself from the position of leading agent of the British East
India
Company to that of a competitor to prosper in the next century.
British Trade Deficit
in Silver Prompted Opium Smuggling into China
In the 18th century, England
was incurring huge trade deficits denominated in silver with China
under Qing dynastic rule, as silver was legal tender in China.
This trade deficit was draining silver from the British Mint at a time
when England
was on the gold standard which undervalued silver, causing silver to
leave England
en mass to effectuate a inflow of gold. Thus British merchants had to
buy silver in continental Europe
with gold at higher prices that cost almost one moreounce of silver for
every ounce of gold sold, becasue of the silver/gold ratio set by
European bimetallim. The price
differential of
silver between England and the Continent continued until Germany
demonetized silver in the 1870s. This meant silver before the 1870s was
priced
higher as a monetary unit in Europe than its intrinsic value as
a
commodity
because of German seigniorage. Silver was also priced lower both
commercially and monetarily in Europe than the
silver/gold ratio set by the gold standard in England.
Because there was not much that China would want to buy from
the West in the 18th century because
China, as
a more advance civilization and a wealthier economy, was producing all
the
goods she needed in superior quality, especially from Britain where
goods
produced by early industrialization were generally crude and
monotonous, the British East India Company resorted to opium smuggling
to China where
opium
trade was illegal to balance the Company's rising trade deficit.
To impose illegal opium trade on China,
the Company soon found it needed to persuade the British government to
adopt
gunboat diplomacy to turn trade into economic and political
imperialism.
Beginning in early 19th century, Britain
became the “Workshop of the World” of crude mass-produced products that
even
members of the British upperclass themselves did not find attractive
and had to be exported to less cultured colonies. But
Chinese markets were too cultured for these goods. Unitl opium
smmugling, the British were unable to break into the huge Chinese
market. Britain
needed more new capital to finance its growing industries and sought it
from
new wealth reaped from overseas colonies. She also needed more raw
materials to
maintain its growing industries and more markets for the finished goods
in a
mercantilist trade regime. She also needed safe shipping routes between
the British Isles and her far-flung colonies.
Lord Palmerston (1784-1865),
liberal successor to the conservative Duke Wellington as Foreign
Secretary in
1830, claimed that Britain
wanted only peace and prestige, a euphemism to justify his gunboat
diplomacy to
expand illegitimate British commercial dominance all over the world.
But China remained ellusive to British colonial ambitions until the
British introduced opium in her China trade.
At home, Palmerston’s expansionist foreign policy ran into conflict
not only with the English landed gentry who opposed trade expansionist
industrialists. The Corn Laws were passed by Parliament to protect
British
agriculture from cheap imports. (See my May 1, 2002 AToL article: Big Money and
the Corn
Laws) Palmerston also clashed with Queen Victoria who wanted
British foreign
policy to avoid creating situations that would weaken monarchism in Europe
which was increasingly threatened by the rising revolutionary ferments
of
republicanism, democracy or socialism, as most royal families were her
blood
relatives through marriage. Her apprehension was not mere
paranoia, as the
German Kaiser and the Russian
Czar both lost their crowns. The Kaiser went into exile in the Netherlands
and lived until 1941. The Russian imperial family lost their lives
through
revolutionary regicide. But on imperialism on non-while peoples, the
Queen
and her
foreign minister were of one mind.
Palmerston launched the First Opium War of 1841 against China,
considered then “the sick man of Asia” by
Europeans. He
was advised by William Jardine, head of Jardine, Matheson and Company,
who
literally planned the entire military operation and drafted the
proposed
surrender terms to be presented to a defeated China.
Easy British victory forced a poorly governed China
open to Western imperialism for the next century. While the British
smuggled
opium to China
from British India, the Forbes and Delano
families of Boston
smuggled opium into China
with
China Clippers from Turkey
grown under British supervision. Much of the profit from the US
opium trade went to Boston
and
through Boston banks to
finance the
expansion of the US West as investments in railroads built mostly with
imported
Chinese slave labor.
The Bengal famine of 1770 caused
liberals in British politics to realize that private companies cannot
be
expected to deal effectively with socio-political issues of mercantile
colonialism. For solution British liberals opted for political
colonialism and
passed the Government of India Act of 1858 to make the British Crown
the direct
ruler of India,
following the so-called Indian Rebellion in 1857, in reality an
independence
struggle brutally suppressed by British forces. The Government of India
Act of
1878 anointed Queen Victoria
with
the title of Empress of India. All properties of the East India Company
were
transferred to the Crown. Its 24,000-man private military force was
incorporated into the British India Army, leaving the Company with only
a
shadow of
the power it had wielded years earlier. The Company, without its
monopoly and
quasi-governmental powers, was finally dissolved on January 1, 1871 by the East
India Stock Dividend
Redemption Act.
The British East India Company throughout its history
naturally had an interest in developing a network of fortified supply
points
along shipping routes from Britain
to India.
As
early as 1620, the Company attempted to lay claim to the Table
Mountain
region overlooking today’s Cape Town
in South Africa
and later occupied it. Cape Town
was a key supply point for shipping to India
as Singapore
was for shipping to China
after the opening of the Suez Cannel in 1869. The rounding of the cape
in 1488
was a major milestone in Portuguese navigational attempts to establish
direct sea trade
routes
to the Far East. The
British East India Company also ruled St.
Helena
where the defeated Napoleon was kept prisoner until death under Company
administration.
Elihu Yale (1649-1721), Boston born but returned with the
family to England at age 4, whose widowed grandmother remarried
Governor
Theophilus Eaton (1590-1657) of the New Haven Colony in Connecticut,
was
connected to the British East India Company for two decades, becoming
the
second governor of Madras in 1687. Yale amassed a
fortune in
his lifetime, largely through secret contracts with native Madras
merchants against company directive. By 1692, repeated flouting of
company
regulations and growing embarrassment at his illegal profiteering led
to Yale’s
being relieved of the post of governor.
In 1718, Cotton Mather (1663-1728), socially and politically
influential New England Puritan minister and pamphleteer, a figure in
the
infamous Salem Witch Trials, asked Elihu Yale in 1701 to help the
Collegiate
School of Connecticut with money for a new building in New
Haven, Connecticut. Yale
sent
Mather a carton of goods that the school subsequently sold for ₤560, a
substantial sum in the early 1700s. In gratitude, officials named the
new
building Yale; eventually the entire institution became Yale
University,
founded initially by
opium smuggling profit from the British East India Company.
Collapse of Chinese
Economy in 19th Century was a Monetary Event
Over the length of two centuries, Britain
devastated the economy of China,
the largest nation in the world, with an ancient, highly developed
civilization
and the rishest economy in the world until the British came in early 19th
century.
The war indemnity of the First Opium War of 1841 alone imposed on China
the payment to Britain
of ₤10 million, ₤3 million of which was for the destruction of
confiscated
opium contraband. Untold millions were subsequently collected from
unequal
treaties forced upon China, the first being the infamous Nanking Treaty
which
among preferential trade concessions granted to British interests,
ceded Hong Kong
to
Britain. The First Opium War showed the West how weak imperial China
really was behind its crumbling superpower facade and opened China
subsequently to a century of foreign aggression and exploitation,
draining
wealth on a massive scale from China
to the European powers, the United
States
and Czarist Russia.
In 1900, the war indemnity from an Eight-Power
Coalition
invasion of China as a result of the xenophobic Boxers Uprising forced
China to
pay 982 million taels (1 tael = 34 grams = 40.76 ounces) or 40 billion
ounces of pure silver at the then
British controlled market
price of three taels per pound sterling, yielding ₤327 million, of
which Russia
received 29%, Germany 20%, France 15%, Britain 11%, Japan 7.7% and the
US 7.3%. This was three times the global
trade deficit
of ₤109 million incurred by Britain in 1910. But the pound sterling was set by the Brtitish
gold standard at 15 ounces of silver, and 982 million taels of silver
covert to 40 billion ounces of silver or ₤2.6 billion, not ₤327 million. The sum of ₤2.6 billion was over 24 times the British global trade
deficit in 1910. This sum and other payment obligations from subsequent
unequal treaties were so large that Britain demanded and received control of Chinese
maritime
custom service to collect tariffs to pay Western Powers their due from
unequal
treaties.
The final collapse of the economy of dynastic China
was caused by the advance of Western political imperialism initially
via the
illegal private smuggling of opium into China,
paid for by a massive outflow of silver from China.
What is yet to be fully recognized by economics historians is the
adverse
effect on the Chinese economy from the massive outward drain of silver
from the
illegal opium trade Britain and the United States imposed on China as a
result
of the inability of the Qing imperial court to protect its sovereignty
and,
more importantly, its independent monetary policy to forbid free trade
in silver.
The collapse of the Qing economy in the 19th century was largely a
monetary
event, with similarity if not congruence with the effects of the Asian
Financial Crisis of 1997 on several of the weaker Asian economies,
notably Thailand,
Indonesia,
Malaysia
and South Korea.
Copper, silver and gold had been the component metals in China’s
tri-metal monetary regime throughout its long history. Cloth, grain,
cattle,
pearls and jade, along with precious metals, had also been used as
media of
exchange in ancient times. Sung dynasty issued the first paper money in
1023. Silver
had been used increasingly widely as currency in China
since the 15th and 16th centuries with imports from the increased
silver
production in the Americas
as a result of a Chinese trade surplus with the West. Around 1564,
Mexican
silver coins began circulating widely in Chinese coastal trade towns
such as Guangzhou
and Fuzhou as payment by
Portuguese traders for
Chinese
exports. By the 18th century, China
was operating on a de facto silver
standard monetary regime.
The 19th-century reversal of China’s
foreign trade from surplus to deficit was due to Western opium
smuggling starting
from 1820. Up to that time, China
permitted very little foreign trade and what legitimate trade that did
take place
amounted to only an insignificant portion of the Chinese economy. This
illegal
opium trade was denominated in silver until China ran short of silver,
after
which the legalized but immoral opium trade was denominated in
porcelain that
steadily fell in price because China could produce porcelain easier
than it
could produce silver, albeit Chinese export porcelain was increasingly
produced
at inferior quality compared to that produced for the more
discriminating
domestic market. Monetary defacement occurred even in porcelain when it
bacame a unit of account.
Maria Alejandra Irigoin in her paper: A
Trojan Horse in 19th century China? The global consequences of
the breakdown of
the Spanish Silver Peso standard, observes
that until the 1640s silver trade was essentially driven
by large differences in the gold silver ratios between Spanish
America, Europe and China,
allowing a substantial arbitrage gain to be realized by intermediaries.
After
1825, China’s
balance of silver trade with the West became negative due to the
illicit opium
trade.
According to Irigoin, between 1719 and 1833, 259 million silver pesos, or 6,321 tons of
silver, entered China
to pay for Chinese goods. That is the equavelent of 421.4 tons or 135.5
million ounces of gold at the universal silver/gold ratio of 15/1. For
comparision, as of January 2007, gold exchange traded funds held 629
tons or of gold in total for private and institutional investors. Of
the 6,321 tons of silver, 62% was introduced after 1785
and a
full 30% after Spanish American independence, usually dated as 1810.
Importantly, the structure of the silver trade was different before and
after
1785. Up to that date, English intermediation accounted for about 50%
of silver
inflow to China
since 1719, French for 20% and Dutch for 15%. After the 1785 the US
became progressively the main provider of silver to China.
Around 1795 North American merchants provided 28% of Chinese silver
inflow to
pay for Chinese goods. By 1799 the US
share had risen to 65% and after 1807 American intermediaries accounted
for a
full 97% of silver inflow into China.
This one-way trade denominated in silver grew steadily until the late
1820s. It
experienced a short-lived high point
in 1834-36 after which date it declined strongly and only staged a
timid
recovery after 1853. US trade deficit with China did not start in the
1990s. It began in 1800.
Despite Chinese discouragement of foreign trade, China had always
enjoyed a trade surplus until 1834. Chinese flow balance of silver had
been
positive all through history and became negative only
after 1826, ten years later than the inversion of the overall balance
of trade
of China
due to
the opium trade. This was because the sliver deficit from the illicit
opium
trade was at first cancelled by silver inflow from Russia
in exchange for Chinese silk, porcelain and tea. Russia
earned silver in the trade boom during the Napoleonic wars. The massive
smuggling
of opium led to increasing silver imbalance for China
after 1819. Similarly, Chinese silver inflow still exceeded outflow
until the
mid-1820s because the US
sent more silver into China
than opium-smuggling English merchants extracted from there to Bengal,
Calcutta
and finally to London.
A spurt of silver demand from China
occurred in the first half of the 18th century, when the Chinese
exchange rate
of silver to gold was still 50% higher than the exchange rate in Europe.
This offered opportunity for European arbitrage with China’s
huge population and market growth.
Irigion notes that the historiography of trade globalization
has long recognized the role of demand for silver in the Chinese
economy as the
foundation in the establishment of intercontinental trade between the Americas,
Europe and Asia
since the 1600s. Silver
from Spanish America reached Europe
through the trade of both Spanish licensed merchants and northern
European
interlopers from whence it continued to flow to China
within the organized trade of the European chartered companies,
primarily the
English and Dutch East India Companies. At the same time a second route
of
silver flows was established within the Spanish colonial trading
system. This
directly linked Spanish American production areas in Peru
and Mexico
to Manila
in the Philippines
through the famous Manila galleon, which sailed
regularly from Acapulco to
the
East.
The monetary changes in Spanish America
in the wake of Spanish American independence impacted upon this trade.
The
revolutionary wars in Spanish America and the
implosion
of the Spanish empire led to a fragmentation of the previously unified
monetary
regime, which resulted in the production of coins of different quality,
fineness and weight. Irigion argues that this change, entirely
exogenous to the
Chinese market, resulted in falling demand for Spanish American pesos
in China.
Thus it
qualifies the conventional historiography that stresses the role of
opium imports
in allegedly reversing the flows of silver bullion to and from China
in the early 1800s, even though it does not altogether negate the
financail impact of opium smmuggling.
Evidence supports the conclusion that monetary conditions exacerbated
the negative effect of opium smuggling on Chinese national finances.
The outflow of silver from China
that began in the early 1800s coincided with the collapse of silver
prices in
the international market as Western countries adopted the gold standard
and
demonetized silver. Silver was leaving China
in huge quantities while the price of silver was falling in the
international
market, making the Chinese trade deficit more expensive in local
currency terms.
Yet while the price of silver fell in the international market, its
price rose
in the Chinese domestic market in relation to copper, accelerating and
exacerbating import trade inflation in the Chinese economy through
domestic
price deflation.
This monetary collapse inflicted great financial damage on China’s
peasantry. While peasant income was denominated in copper coins, their
tax
obligation to the imperial court was denominated in silver coins,
because the
imperial government’s trade deficit was denominated in silver. The
scarcity of
silver created by the massive outflow pushed the domestic silver price
sky-high
in terms of copper coins. A similar monetary disadvantage is now
hurting
American workers whose wages are denominated in falling dollars with
dwindling
purchasing power for critical imports such as oil. The only different
is that
for 19th century China, the damage was forced on the Chinese
peasantry by foreign imperialism, while in the US, the damage on US
workers
were done by their own government’s monetary and trade policy.
International bimetallism greatly disadvantaged the Chinese
silver-based export economy and domestic bimetallism greatly
disadvantaged the
copper-based finances of the Chinese peasantry. Chinese peasant
populists would
have a similar incentive to promote a copper-based monetary regime
against a
silver standard in China
as the US
populists did with fighting for a silver-based monetary system against
the gold
standard in the US.
But until the Chinese Communist Party gained control of the
governmental
apparatus of the nation, there was no official defender of the Chinese
peasantry.
China
suffered a
protracted two-century-long economic recession all through the 19th and
20th
centuries as it came into commercial contact with the West. This
two-century-long recession reduced China
from being the richest economy in the world to one of the poorest. It
was the
result of the structural monetary double disadvantage of international
bi-metallism
of gold and silver superimposed on the silver-based monetary system of
the Chinese
foreign trade sector. This took place in a world monetary regime
shifting
toward the gold standard, which greatly disadvantaged the Chinese
domestic
bimetal monetary system of copper and silver. This double disadvantage
fatally
wounded the Chinese economy for two centuries, causing the decline of a
highly
developed culture with an uninterrupted history of four millennia and
halted
its further development for more than seven generations over two
centuries. The
bankrupt economy reduced the Qing imperial China
to a failed state unable to defend itself from aggressive Western
imperialist powers
until the founding of the People’s Republic when China
adopted a socialist path for its economy. Even after the 1911 bourgeois
revolution
that established the Republic of China under the Goumindang
(Nationalist
Party), when China
followed a petty bourgeois free market system, she was unable to shake
off
Western imperialism to free the nation, once the most prosperous in the
world,
from semi-colonial economic status. In that sense, China
is different historically from many other nations of the Third
World
that had never achieved comparable prosperity, albeit many Third
World nations were much better off before falling victim to
Western imperialism. The two non-European nations that matched China’s
level of
socio-economic and cultural achievements were Ancient Egypt and the
Ottoman
Empire, the modern descendent entity of which are but a shadow of their
former
greatness.
Beside economic exploitation, the British East India Company, to gain
political support from the Church of England for colonialism, also
adopted
aggressive evangelistic policies on behalf of Christianity. The deep
hostility
between Catholicism and Protestantism was buried within British
imperialism.
Many British empire-builders were Scots who brought with them Scottish
Catholicism to the non-white British colonies. The Act of Union of 1707
united
the kingdoms of England
and Scotland
and transfered the seat of Scottish Government to London.
Henceforth England
and Scotland
are known as the United Kingdom.
The Company methodically destroyed monasteries and
suppressed indigenous culture in Buddhist Tibet, which together with
its
launching of the Opium Wars to protect its immoral opium smuggling,
caused
deep-rooted anti-Western xenophobia in all Asia that lingers on even
today and
makes travesty of belated Western grandstanding on religious freedom,
human
rights and rule of law in centuries to come.
The British Pound
Sterling and the Gold Standard
The pound sterling, created in 1560 by Elizabeth
I, as advised by Thomas Gresham, brought order to the monetary chaos of
Tudor
England that had been caused by the “Great Debasement” of coinage,
having
caused a decade-long debilitating inflation beginning in 1543 when the
silver
content of a penny dropped by two thirds to become mere fiduciary
currency. The
exchange rate of British coins collapsed in Antwerp
where English cloth was sold in Europe.
The Bank of England was founded 1694 with the pound sterling
as the currency of account. All coins in
circulation were then recalled by the Royal Mint for re-mint at a
higher
standard. Sterling
unofficially
moved to the gold standard from silver as a result of an overvaluation
of gold
in England
that
drew gold from abroad in exchange for a steady outflow of silver,
notwithstanding a re-evaluation of gold in 1717 by Isaac Newton as
Master of
the Royal Mint. The de facto gold standard continued until its
official
adoption following the end of the Napoleonic Wars in 1816. The
gold
standard lasted until Britain,
along with several other trading countries, abandoned it only after
World War I
in 1919. During this period, the pound was generally valued at around $4.90. Britain tried to restored the gold standard in
1925 without success despite support from the US central bank which
contributed to the 1929 crash on Wall street that immediately spread to
world markets to cuase a global depression.
The
currencies of all other major Western countries in 1821 were either
bimetallic
or specie-backed paper money. This meant that Britain operated within a floating exchange
rate system for most of the 19th century, although for much of this
time, when
the silver/gold ratio stayed close to the common mint ratio of 15.5/1,
the
floats were tightly constrained within a narrow band. Nineteenth
century gold standard
was supported by government incentives and government ability to adhere
to it
due to lower borrowing costs (on average 40 basis points) when loans
were
denominated in currency backed by gold, especially in London, the center of international finance at the
time. Hence large borrowers, like the newly independent US, had a
strong
incentive to also adopt the gold standard. By 1870, the main core
countries of
gold standard had been deeply engaged in international trade for
decades, led
by British promotion of free trade. Consequently
their respective domestic price
levels were similar and
their differences changed only slowly, putting less strain on their
balance of
payments. Trade deficits were difficult to sustain and trade would slow
as
deficits mounted until balance of payments were restored.
British
promotion of free trade under the gold standard in an era when new
discovery of
gold in the Americas, Australia and South Africa allowed Britain to run a trade deficit while still fund
substantial investment in colonies overseas. This was because gold was
steadily
devalued on expectation of more gold entering the market and the
resultant
defacement was expected to be corrected as the economy expanded faster
than the
rate of gold production. It was a classic example of the positive
effects of
the quantity theory of money when money supply expansion did not come
from official defacement of currency even as gold was devalued.
Key
difference between Pound Sterling Hegemony
and Dollar Hegemony
Earlier in
the 19th century, Britain had to run a trade surplus in order
to invest overseas. An increase supply of gold translated into an
increase in
money supply to boost economic growth globally after mid century.
Overseas
income in turn acted as counterbalance against temporary adverse trade
flows
and balance of payments and thereby reduced the need for aggressive
moves in
interest rates. Globally, wealth was flowing to England from the rest of the world even as England incurred persistent trade
deficits. This is the same principle
behind dollar hegemony today that allows wealth to flow into the dollar
economy
controlled by the US even as the US incurs persistent trade and fiscal
deficits. The key difference is that the dollar today is not protected
by
economic expansion against devaluation, since the Federal Reserve under
Alan
Greenspan had resorted to devaluation of the dollar as a device to
stimulate
serial economic bubbles. China needs to understand that there is
no future in participating in a global trade regime with the dollar as
reserve
currency.
The
ever-widening spread of a multilateral trading system also reduced the
need to
settle trade deficits in gold. In 1910, Britain ran a combined trade deficit of
£107 million with three large regions: Continental Europe, the US and the great plain nations of Canada, Australia and Argentina. But she partially offset that
deficit with a £60 million trade surplus with the non-white
British colonies of India, British Caribbean and Africa. In turn, these non-white British
colonies had trade surpluses of £40 million with Continental
Europe, the US, and the great plain nations.
British trade surplus with semi-colonial China was not included in these numbers.
US Populism
and the Gold Standard
There was
international consensus that the monetary discipline imposed by the
gold standard
ensured good policy, a belief buttressed by a general political
acquiescence
within the core trading economies through central bank co-ordination
and
capital decontrol. The exception was the US which did not have a central bank
until 1913.
US
populists were fighting against the
gold standard in favour of bimetallism in the 1860s, because the gold
standard
was deflationary and would and did hurt farmers with farm mortgages. Populist
in the US
felt
that greenbacks not backed by a gold standard would allow credit to
flow more
freely to rural farm regions at lower interest rates where more farm
credit was
needed. Free silver platform also received widespread support across
class
lines in the Mountain states where the economy was heavily dependent
upon
silver mining. Western Silver Republicans became active in US politics.
In the
1896 presidential election, Democratic candidate William Jennings Bryan
backed
the Populist opposition to the gold standard in his famous “Cross of
Gold”
speech. The populist Democrats lost and the gold standard prevailed
because market-driven co-operation helped
make central-bank intervention rates set in London remarkably effective.
Gresham’s Law of Bad Money Driving out Good
For centuries, money in Europe
consisted of both silver and gold coins. When governments introduced
specie-backed paper money, they specified the value of the paper
currency in
terms of weights of either silver or gold. A bimetal monetary system
bases its
money on both gold and silver at a fixed ratio, with 15 ounces of
silver
equaling to 1 ounce of gold set by Louis XIV France, the hegemon in Europe
at the time.
As market prices of silver and gold fluctuated, as for
example market price of gold rose above the ratio against silver set by
the
mint, making gold “good” money, gold holders could buy silver in the
market and
exchange the silver for gold at the Treasury, draining gold from it,
forcing
silver to be the only standard eventually. In United States, because
the 15/1
ratio of 1792 overvalued silver as money in terms of market price of
the metal
because of increased silver supply from mines, silver became the
standard, and
the money supply in effect expanded, causing inflation. Then when the
ratio was
changed in 1834 to 16/1, it was gold which was overvalued so that gold
became
finally the standard, and the money supply shrank, causing deflation.
This
effect is captured by Gresham’s law which states that “bad money will drive out
good”. Gresham's
law applies when two forms of commodity money are in circulation as
legal
tenders which require their acceptance for payment of debts and taxes
at face
value, the undervalued good will disappear from circulation as money,
and will
be used as commodity to capture its higher market value.
In Napoleonic Europe, silver continued as standard as it did
in the US
up to
1834. The first gold coin issued in England
in 1663 was the Guinea,
worth one pound sterling or twenty shillings (44½ guineas would
be made from
one Troy pound of 11/12 finest gold, each
weighing 129.4
grains). The gold used to mint the Guinea
came from Guinea,
Africa, hence its name. As the
price of gold rose over time,
a Guinea
was
worth as much as 30 shillings. By the 1680s the guinea had settled down
to
worth 22 shillings. Isaac Newton, the physicist, when acting as Master
of the
Mint in 1717, set the price of the British gold Guinea
at 20 shillings 8 pence (which corresponded with 76 shillings 7.6 pence
per
22-carat ounce of 0.9167 fine gold).
Newton’s
Mint
Reports [in Old English]:
On
the Proportion of Gold and Silver in Value in several European
Currencies
(Sept. 1701).
By
the late Edicts of the French
King for raising the monies in France
the proportion of the value of Gold to that of Silver being altered, I
humbly
presume to give yr Lordps notice thereof. By the last of those Edicts
the Lewis
d'or passes for fourteen Livres & the Ecus or French crown for
three livres
& sixteen sols. At wch rate the Lewis d'or is worth 16s. 7d.
sterling,
supposing the Ecus worth 4s. 6d. as it is recconed in the court of
exchange
& as I have found it by some Assays. The proportion therefore
between Gold
& Silver is now become the same in France
as it has been in Holland
for some
years. For at Amsterdam
the Lewis
d'or passes for 9 Guilders and nine or ten styvers wch in our money
amounts to
16s. 7d. & it has past at this rate for the last five or six years.
At
the same rate a Guinea
of due weight, & allay is worth £ 1, 0s. 11 d.
In
Spain Gold is recconed (in
stating accompts) worth sixteen times its weight of silver of the same
allay,
at wch rate a Guinea of due weight and allay is worth 1£ 2s. 1 d.
but the
Spaniards make their payments in Gold & will not pay in Silver
without an
abatement. This abatement is not certain, but rises & falls
according as Spain
is supplied with Gold or Silver from the Indies.
Last
winter it was about five per cent.
The
state of the money in France
being unsetled, whether it may afford a sufficient argument for
altering the
proportion of the values of Gold & Silver monies in England
is most humbly submitted to yor Lordps great wisdome.
On
the Value of Gold and Silver in English, Irish and European Coins (Mar.
- June
1712).
Gold
is over-valued in England
in Proportion to Silver, by at least 9d. or 10d. in a Guinea, and this
Excess
of Value tends to increase the Gold Coins, and diminish the Silver
Coins of
this Kingdom; and the same will happen in Ireland by the like
overvaluing of Gold in that Kingdom.
On
the Value of Gold and Silver in
European Currencies and the Consequences on the World-wide Gold- and
Silver-Trade (Sept. 1717).
In
France
a pound weight of fine gold is recconed worth fifteen pounds weight of
fine
silver.
In
China
and Japan
one
pound weight of fine gold is worth but nine or ten pounds weight of
fine
silver, & in East India it may be worth
twelve. And
this low price of gold in proportion to silver carries away the silver
from all Europe.
Parliament modified Newton’s
precise ratio and set the guinea at 21 shillings even, corresponding to
77
shillings and 10.5 pence per standard ounce 22-carat gold.
This required Newton
to increase the mint price of gold by 1 shilling 2.9 pence in order to
make 89
guinea coins out of two troy pounds of 22-carat gold at Parliament’s
price. In truth, Parliament had in mind
more than rounding off numbers. It purposely overvalued gold to
introduce the
gold standard in England’s
monetary regime.
French hegemony under Louis XIV had allowed the Sun King to
set a silver/gold ratio at 15/1 in Europe. For
English
money to be at par with the same ratio, Newton
recommended to Parliament that the value of the Guinea
gold coin be set only 8 pence above 20 shillings. When Parliament set
the value
of a Guinea coin at 21 shillings (4 pence above the equilibrium price
of the
15/1 ratio proposed by Newton), it was an act of deliberate policy that
set off
a chain reaction which ultimately led to replacing silver/gold
bimetalism with
the gold standard.
Silver then became the “good money” (undervalued monetarily)
and gold the “bad” money in England
while gold became the “good” money and silver the “bad” money in Europe.
The policy of overvaluing gold drew gold to England
at the expense of silver, driving silver out of its role as money in England.
Because gold was thereby set to buy more silver in England
than it did in continental Europe, Gresham’s
Law of bad money driving out good would compel traders to buy gold with
silver
on the continent, sell the gold in England
for silver, and take their proceeds in silver back to the continent for
the
next round of gold purchasing. Gresham's Law did not "invent" the
gold/silver carry trade, Sir Thomas Gresham, founder of the Royal
Exchange, only providing a simple explanation of it in a letter to
Elizabeth I on the occasion of her accession in 1558, two years before
the creation of the pound sterling. Currency carry trade has been going
on since
money
started circulating across national borders. It had been observed by
Corpernicus in his Monetae cudendae
ratio written in 1526 based on an earlier report to the
Prussian
Diet of 1522, but published only posthumously in 1816.
Raising the exchange value of the RMB against the dollar in
a freely convertible exchange regime will turn the RMB into “bad” money
in Gresham’s
Law and make the dollar into “good” money, even though China
is a creditor nation to the US.
Under such relationship, hot money denominated in fiat dollars will
rush into
China to change into RMB to get the benefit of higher interest rates
and
further exchange rate appreciation and reconvert the “carry trade”
profit back
into dollars, in the form of net wealth, to flow from China back into
the US
even when the dollar is a fiat currency and the RMB is a only a
derivative
currency of the dollar.
Throughout history, pressuring another country to alter the
exchange value of its currency has been recognized as acts of monetary
aggression. To resist this monetary aggression, China
needs break away from the tyranny of dollar hegemony. To do this, a
full
understanding of history of monetary imperialism is necessary.
August 28, 2008
Next:
History
of Monetary Imperialism
|