Critique of Central Banking
By
Henry C K Liu
Part I: Monetary
theology
Part II:
The European Experience
Part III-a: The US
Experience
Part III-b: More on the US
experience
Part III-c: Still More on
the US Experience<>
Part
III-d: The Lesson of the
US Experience
Part 4a: The Asian experience
Since
the beginning of the new
millennium, the world's three leading economies, the United States, the
European Union and Japan, have experienced a rare synchronous slowdown
while much of the developing world, including Asia, remained mired in
economic and financial difficulties that started in Asia in 1997.
This
development has rendered inoperative the strategy of having the global
economic engine stabilized by sequential boosts from the synchronized
phasing of domestic business cycles in connected yet independent
economies, like the well-timed sequential firing of a multi-cylinder
internal combustion engine. The current global economic stagnation is
not an accidental breakdown. It is the visible result of the
coordinated operation of global central banking, burning out the
economic spark plugs with super-rich gas in the form of universal and
reflexive tight monetary measures, which have produced overlapping
long-term imbalances in the global economy's major regional dynamos.
The
decade-long post-bubble deflation in Japan was linked to financial
globalization that challenged the efficacy of the traditional Japanese
financial system. The Tokyo Big Bang (financial deregulation) on April
1, 1998, crowned with a Central Bank Law on the same day, was designed
to boost the value of the Japanese stock market, aiming to re-establish
Tokyo's position as one of the top three global financial centers. Once
the largest stock market in the world, Tokyo by 1998 had fallen
steadily to less than half the size of New York in contrast with the
latter's astronomical expansion. Although the Japanese had savings of
about US$9 trillion in 1998, a third of the world total, most savings
were held in low-interest bank and postal accounts on which the
Japanese government traditionally relied for low-cost capital to fund
its national economic plans. The population was aging rapidly and the
government was worried there would not be enough money in the economy
to support future pensioners because of the low return on savings.
Neo-liberal
market fundamentalists pushed through a series of radical reforms
designed to change the way money traditionally flowed around the
Japanese economy, recycling more savings into the stock market to boost
yield. The government hoped to bring Tokyo back in line with the high
trading levels of London and New York, pulling the value of the
recycled savings up with it by increasing their rate of return. The
reforms were called the Big Bang after a similar exercise in Britain 12
years earlier on October 27, 1986, which in turn was inspired by May
Day in the US in 1975, which ended fixed minimum brokerage commissions
that marked the beginning of diversification into electronic trading.
Instead
of bringing new prosperity and high returns to fund exploding pension
obligations, the Tokyo Big Bang reduced Japanese banks, which earlier
had been operating with spectacular success in a national banking
regime in support of Japanese industrial policy, to near-terminal cases
in a global central banking environment. Subsidized policy loans that
had served postwar national purposes for half a century suddenly became
non-performing loans (NPLs) as defined by new international standards
set by the Bank of International Settlement (BIS), as corporate
borrowers were forced by dollar hegemony to sacrifice profit margin to
expand market share, while financial deregulation put downward pressure
on the traditional norm of high price-earning ratios of Japanese
equity. The banks' traditional holding of significant equity position
in their corporate borrowers and the tradition of a controlled domestic
market caused structural problems for the Japanese financial system in
the new globalized competitive environment. The banks were squeezed by
falling cash flow from loan service payments by their distressed
debtors and by the falling market value of loan collateral and capital
held in the shares of their borrowers.
The
Tokyo stock market's key Nikkei index tumbled from an all-time high of
21,552.81 recorded on June 13, 1994, to below the psychologically
crucial 15,000 level in July 1995 when the yen's sharp appreciation hit
manufacturers and exporters. The Nikkei is now around 8,500 and
Japanese officials would kill to get it back to 15,000, but it seems to
be an impossible dream because global central banking has forced
deregulated markets to discount the market value of the Japanese system
that had worked so miraculously for the previous half-century. The
government tried to solve the problem with Keynesian deficit financing,
only to be hit with international credit-rating downgrades on
government bonds, despite the fact that Japan remains the world's
biggest credit nation.
Concurrently
in Europe, persistently high levels of unemployment and anemic growth
plagued the euro zone, whose European Central Bank (ECB) came into
being on June 1, 1998, two months after Japan's. And in the United
States, by the beginning of 2000, a steady collapse of the debt bubble
began, generated by unsustainably high consumer, business and external
debt levels that had been first engineered by the Federal Reserve (Fed)
through regulatory indulgence and then later deflated through sharp
rises in interest rates.
Since
then, the global economic engine has been stalled in all three
cylinders by the efforts of the world's three dominant central banks to
impose on the global economy destructively inoperative monetary
policies.
After
allowing regulatory indulgence on the part of the US Security and
Exchange Commission (SEC) to feed a historic bubble in US asset prices
inflated by accounting fantasies, fraudulent analyses, and financial
manipulation, the Fed, reversing its loose monetary policy since 1997,
conducted a pre-election monetary tightening, repeatedly raising
interest rates in quick succession during the second half of 1999 and
the first half of 2000 to slow down the real economy. The Fed also
spurred the ECB to follow suit, despite already slow growth and high
unemployment in EU member economies.
The
Fed had discovered that for the United States, domestic consumer price
stability in an expanding economy could be achieved through a
strong-currency policy that would generate a capital account surplus to
finance a current-account deficit that produced a low inflation reading
through low-cost imports, as long as key commodities, such as oil, were
denominated in US currency. For a whole decade, wealth has been created
primarily through financial acrobatics, not real economic expansion
either within the US or around the world. Conspicuous consumption along
chic shopping boulevards, cruised by gas-guzzling sport-utility
vehicles, to fill homes that rose in price by 60 percent annually,
supported by the wealth effect of a stock-market bubble that made
office clerical workers millionaires, buoyant by a trade regime that
enabled a massive transfer of wealth from the poor to the super rich,
is mistaken for economic growth. Fed chairman Alan Greenspan proudly
called this US financial hegemony and told Congress that the financial
crises that hit Asia in 1997 would have "salutary" effect on the US
economy.
During
the past decade, central banks worldwide have achieved unprecedented
heights of policy dominance through their function as chief guardians
of strong national currencies in globalized, unregulated financial
markets. Simultaneously, monetary authorities the world over have been
promoting the doctrine of central-bank independence from duly
constituted national governments and their national economic policies,
as if populist government and people-oriented policies are financial
evils that must be resisted. Poverty and unemployment are hailed as the
foundation of sound money that should not be jeopardized by political
pressure. This elitist doctrine is fundamentally incompatible with a
political world order of independent nation states and the principle of
consent of the governed. Any nation that forfeits its monetary
prerogative also forfeits its political independence.
The
ECB's institutional structure represents the ultimate real-world
application of this doctrine on a regional scale. In the name of
central-bank autonomy, the Maastricht Treaty explicitly prohibits the
ECB from seeking or taking instruction from constituent national
governments, or European Community institutions such as the European
Parliament, or "any other body", and bars constituent national
governments from attempting to influence the decisions of the ECB.
Critics have pointed out that those same rules place no reciprocal
restrictions on the ECB's policy advocacy. ECB president Wim Duisenberg
has unreservedly pushed euro zone economies to refashion their labor,
product, services, capital and credit markets along neo-liberal
market-fundamentalist lines, even in economies under social democratic
governments. This has contributed to the EU's slow growth and high
unemployment. Germany, the dominant economy in the EU, has persistently
suffered high unemployment, which hit 9.7 percent in November, rising
above the politically sensitive 4 million level; in eastern Germany,
the unemployment rate was 17.6 percent.
Article
105 of the Maastricht Treaty states clearly: "The primary objective of
the European System of Central Banks shall be to maintain price
stability." The wording of the Maastricht Treaty was not so much
influenced by economic insights as it was written in a very specific
political context: to persuade an inflation-averse Germany to exchange
the deutschmark for the euro, by guaranteeing the stability of the new
currency. This explains the focus on price stability and the fact that
other objectives were mentioned separately and secondarily. The
statutes of other central banks, such as the Fed, can be changed by
action of a single legislature. The ECB would require all 15 member
states and their parliaments to change the treaty that defines the
structure and institutional mandate of the ECB. This makes the ECB one
of the most independent central banks in the world. The treaty did not
define "price stability", leaving a vacuum quickly filled by the new
and independent ECB by defining price stability as "an inflation rate
that does not exceed 2 percent over the medium term", a very tight
definition by any standard. Interest-rate policy alone is an inadequate
tool because a single instrument cannot hit multiple targets.
Furthermore, using interest rates to control asset markets risks
inflicting significant collateral damage on the rest of the economy,
which was exactly what happened in the past few years.
The
BIS harbors latent ambitions to turn itself into a de facto World
Central Bank (WCB) with the ECB as a model, while the argument for the
need for a WCB is floated around in the upper reaches of
internationalist monetary circles.
Asia
is home to 58 percent of the world's 6.25 billion people, with 43
percent of Asians living in East Asia and 37 percent in China alone.
According to US Central Intelligence Agency (CIA) data, the US economy
accounts for 21 percent of gross world product (GWP - $47 trillion in
2001), the EU accounts for 20 percent and Japan accounts for 7.3
percent. The three leading economies together account for $22 trillion
- 47.3 percent of GWP.
China,
the second-largest economy in the world based on purchasing power
parity (PPP; 12 percent of GWP), and seventh on a nominal basis ($1.3
trillion in 2001, 2.8 percent of GWP) is an exception to global trends
of slow growth, continuing its rapid annual growth, officially
announced as 7.3 percent in 2001 and 8 percent in 2002. Yet lest we
should get carried away by statistics, the Chinese per capita gross
domestic product (GDP) of about $900 in 2001 remains solidly in the
less-developed-countries (LDC) category, way below Japan's $32,500. Of
the 129 countries covered by the World Development Report, China ranked
76th in per capita GDP on a nominal basis and 68th on a PPP basis, a
modest climb. China's economic strength rests purely on its size. China
also adopted a Central Bank Law in 1995 and gave the People's Bank of
China central-bank status, but the Chinese economy has remained a
growth economy mostly because its currency is not freely convertible
and its financial market is not open, and its central bank not fully
independent.
There
is increasing evidence that the crisis in the Japanese banking system
is not the cause but merely the symptom of that nation's economic
malaise. This malaise can largely be traced to the Japanese economy's
over-dependence on export for dollars, which in turn has resulted from
the disadvantaged structural financial position Japan has allowed
itself to fall into in the global financial system. BIS regulations,
which force traditional Japanese national banking in support of a
strong economy to shift toward central banking in support of a strong
national currency, are a big part of that structural disadvantage. This
is the reason Japan has been resistant to US demands for bank reform.
The NPL problem in Japanese banks traces directly to BIS regulations.
This is also true for all of Asia, particularly South Korea, and
increasingly China. No doubt Japan needs to reform its banking system,
but it is highly debatable that the reform needs to go along the line
proposed by US neo-liberals, or that bank reform alone will lift the
Japanese economy out of its decade-long doldrums (see The
BIS vs national banks, May 14, 2002).
All
these problems contributed to and in turn were magnified by structural
flaws and disorders in the international financial architecture and
global trade, notably misaligned currency values and interest rate
disparities. This has led to escalating mismatches between productive
capacity and effective demand, which has been exacerbated by a "free
trade" regime that has degenerated into a mad scramble for dollars that
the United States can print at will. The whole world lives on an
over-reliance on export to a US consumer market fueled by debt
sustained by dollar hegemony. The ABC of the global economy is now
expressed as America prints dollars to Buy the world's
products on Credit provided by the world's producers. The US is
exempt from a day of reckoning, since the US only has to print more
dollars, as Fed Board member Ben Bernanke pronounced recently. Foreign
creditors will only devalue their massive dollar holdings if they try
to collect from the US economy. It is the ultimate demonstration of
debtor power, with the debtor holding the power to print currency in
which the debt is denominated. Asia, because of its largest population
of low-wage workers, is holding the shortest end of the biggest global
trade stick.
The
Asian financial crisis that began in 1997 had its genesis in Mexico,
incubated by a decade of globalization of financial markets. The
currency crisis that started in Mexico in 1982, in Britain in 1992,
again in Mexico in 1994, in Asia in 1997, spreading to Russia and Latin
America since and finally hitting both the EU and the US in 2000, and
the deeper structural financial challenges facing the entire global
economy, have been the inevitable result of the Fed, the ECB and the
Bank of Japan applying their unified institutional mandates of domestic
price stability through domestic interest-rate policies that have
destabilized the post-Bretton Woods international finance architecture.
The
Mexican financial crisis of 1982 set the pattern for subsequent
financial crises around the world. To recycle petrodollars beginning in
1973, US banks had sought out select LDCs, such as Brazil, Mexico,
Argentina, South Korea, Taiwan, the Philippines, Indonesia, etc, for
predatory lending. By 1980, LDCs had accumulated $400 billion in
foreign debt, more than their combined GDP. In 1982, impacted by the
Fed under Paul Volcker raising dollar interest rates sharply in 1979 to
fight inflation in the United States, Mexico was put in a position of
not being able to meet its obligations to service $80 billion in
dollar-denominated short-term debt obligations to foreign, mostly US,
banks out of a GDP of $106 billion. Debt service payments reached 62.8
percent of export value in 1979. Exports accounted for 12 percent of
GDP while government expenditures accounted for 11 percent, which
included public-education expenditure of 5.2 percent. Mexico was paying
more in interest to foreign banks than it did to educate its young.
Mexican foreign reserves had fallen to less than $200 million and
capital was leaving the country at the rate of $100 million a day.
Against this background, neo-liberal economists were claiming that
poverty was being eradicated in Mexico by "free" trade, a claim they
made the world over.
A
Mexican default would have threatened the survival of the largest
commercial banks in the United States, namely Citibank, Chase,
Chemical, Bank of America, Bankers Trust, Manufacturer Hanover, etc. To
negotiate new loans for Mexico, all creditors would have to agree and
participate, so that the new loans would not just go pay off some
holdout creditors at the expense of the others. Many other creditor
banks were smaller US regional banks that had only limited exposure to
Mexico, and they did not want to "throw good money after bad" merely to
bail out the major money center banks. The big banks had to lobby the
Fed to step in as crisis manager to keep the smaller banks in line for
the good of the system, notwithstanding that the crisis had been caused
largely by the Fed's failure to impose prudent limits on the money
center banks' frenzied lending to the Third World in the previous
decade and Volcker's sudden high-interest-rate shock treatment in 1979,
instead of traditional Fed gradualism that would have given the banks
time to adjust their loan portfolios. Third World economies were
falling likes flies from the weight of debts that suddenly became
prohibitive to service, not much different from private businesses in
the United States, except that countries could not go bankrupt to wipe
out debt the way private business could in the US. Volcker's triumph
over domestic inflation was bought with the destabilization of the
international financial system, whose banks had acted like loan sharks
in the Third World with Fed approval. The International Monetary Fund
then came in to take over the impaired bank loans with austerity
"conditionalities" forced on the debtor economies, while the foreign
banks went home whole with the IMF new money.
As a
result, Third World economies, including those in Asia, fell into a
debt spiral, having to borrow new money from the IMF to service the old
debts, being forced by new loan "conditionalities" to forgo any hope of
future prosperity. Living standards kept declining while foreign debts
kept piling higher, leading to even higher unemployment and more
bankruptcies.
US
banks, while continuing to advocate free markets and financial
deregulation, were at the same time falling into total dependence on
government bailouts, both domestically and internationally. US
taxpayers were footing the bill the Fed incurred in bailing out its
constituent banks, through higher government budget deficits, which
contributed to higher inflation, which led to higher interest rates,
which in turn intensified the Third World debt spiral, in one huge
vicious circle.
By
the late 1980s, Mexico had temporarily resolved its debt crisis, though
not its debt spiral, and was able to resume a Ponzi-scheme economic
growth, relying to a great extent on rising foreign investment. To
attract more foreign capital, the Mexican government, coached by
neo-liberal market-fundamentalist economists, undertook major economic
reforms in the early 1990s designed to make its economy more open to
foreign investment, more "efficient", and more "competitive",
neo-liberal code words for disguised neo-imperialism. These reforms
included privatizing state-owned enterprises, removing trade barriers
that protected domestic producers, eliminating restrictions on foreign
investment, and reducing inflation by tolerating higher unemployment
and pushing down already low wages and limiting government spending on
social programs by marketizing them. Most important, it suspended
exchange control within a fixed-foreign-exchange-rate regime.
This
was in essence a Washington Consensus solution and much copied all over
Asia in the early 1990s. In effect, it was a suicidal policy masked by
the giddy expansion typical of the early phase of a Ponzi scheme. The
new foreign investment was used to provide spectacular returns on
earlier foreign investment with the help of central-bank support of
overvalued fixed exchange rates, while neo-liberal economists were
falling over one another congratulating themselves on their brilliant
theoretical insight and giving one another awards at insider dinners,
while collecting fat consultant fees from banks and governments. Star
academics at Harvard, Massachusetts Institute of Technology (MIT),
Chicago and Stanford, multiple snake heads of the academic Medusa, as
well as those in prestigious policy-analysis institutions with
unabashed ideological preferences that served as waiting lounges for
policy specialists of the loyal opposition, busily turned out star
disciples from the Third World elite who, armed with awe-inspiring
foreign certificates and diplomas, would return to their home countries
to form influential policy-making establishments, particularly in
central banks, to promote this scandalous game of snake-oil economics.
Every year, sponsored by the IMF and the World Bank, central bankers
gathered in Washington, housed in luxurious hotel suites served by
fleets of limousines to reassure one another of their monetary magic,
communicating through opaque press releases couched in cryptic jargon.
Mexico's
devaluation of the peso in December 1994 precipitated another crisis in
the country's financial institutions and markets that caused an abrupt
collapse of a "booming" economy that had not benefited Mexico as much
as foreign capital. Within Mexico, most of the benefit went to the
elite comprador class at the expense of the general population,
particularly the poor but even the middle class. International and
domestic investors, reacting to falling confidence in the peso, sold
Mexican equity and debt securities. Foreign-currency reserves at the
Bank of Mexico, the nation's central bank, were insufficient to meet
the massive demand of disillusioned investors seeking to convert pesos
to dollars. In response to the crisis, the United States organized a
financial rescue package of up to $50 billion in funds from the US,
Canada, the IMF and the BIS. The multilateral rescue package was
intended to enable Mexico to avoid defaulting on its debt obligations,
and thereby overcome its short-term liquidity crisis, and to prevent
the crisis from spreading to other emerging markets through contagion.
It was not to help a Mexican economy hemorrhaging from a bankrupt
monetary policy, one that allowed international investors to collect
their phantom Ponzi peso profits in real dollars. The Mexican rescue
package in 1995 created moral hazard on a global scale.
In
the weekend before Mexico's pending default, the US government took the
lead in developing a rescue package. The package put together by the
Fed under Alan Greenspan and the Treasury under Robert Rubin, a former
co-chairman of Goldman Sachs and a consummate bond trader, included
short-term currency swaps from the Fed and the Exchange Stabilization
Fund (ESF), a commitment from Mexico to an IMF-imposed economic
austerity program for $4 billion in IMF loans, and a moratorium on
Mexico's principal payments to foreign commercial banks, mostly US,
with Fed regulatory forbearance on bank capital adjustments that
affected bank profits. It also included $5 billion in additional
commercial bank loans, additional liquidity support from central banks
in Europe and Japan, and prepayment by the US to Mexico for $1 billion
in oil, and a $1 billion line of credit from the US Department of
Agriculture.
The
ESF was established by Section 20 of the Gold Reserve Act of January
1934, with a $2-billion initial appropriation. Its resources has been
subsequently augmented by special drawing rights (SDR) allocations by
the IMF and through its income over the years from interest on
short-term investments and loans, and net gains on foreign currencies.
The ESF engages in monetary transactions in which one asset is
exchanged for another, such as foreign currencies for dollars, and can
also be used to provide direct loans and guarantees to other countries.
ESF operations are under the control of the Secretary of the Treasury,
subject to the approval of the president. ESF operations include
providing resources for exchange-market intervention. The ESF has also
been used to provide short-term swaps and guarantees to foreign
countries needing financial assistance for short-term currency
stabilization. The short-term nature of these transactions has been
emphasized by amendments to the ESF statute requiring the president to
notify Congress if a loan or credit guarantee is made to a country for
more than six months in any 12-month period.
It
was Bear Stearns chief economist Wayne Angell, a former Fed governor
and advisor to then Senate majority leader Bob Dole, who first came up
with the idea of using the ESF to prop up the collapsing Mexican peso.
Bear Stearns had significant exposure to peso debts. Senator Robert
Bennett, a freshman Republican from Utah, took Angell's proposal to
Greenspan and Rubin, who both rejected the idea at first, shocked at
the blatant circumvention of constitutional procedures that this
strategy represented, which would invite certain reprisal from
Congress. Congress had implicitly rejected a rescue package that
January when the initial proposal of extending Mexico $40 billion in
loan guarantees could not get enough favorable votes. The chairman of
the Fed advised Bennett that the idea would only work if Congress's
silence could be guaranteed. Bennett went to Dole and convinced him
that the whole scam would work if the majority leader would simply
block all efforts to bring this use of taxpayers' money to a vote. It
would all happen by executive fiat. The next step was to persuade Dole
and his counterpart in the House, Speaker Newt Gingrich. They consulted
several state governors, notably then Texas governor George W Bush, who
enthusiastically endorsed the idea of a bailout to subsidize the border
region in his state. Greenspan, who historically opposed bailouts of
the private sector for fear of incurring moral hazard, was clearly in a
position to stop this one. Instead, he used his considerable power and
influence to help the process along when key players balked.
The
peso bailout would lead to a series of similar situations in which
private investors got themselves into trouble, vindicating the
moral-hazard principle that predicts such people will take undue risks
in the presence of bailout guarantees. As Thailand, Indonesia,
Malaysia, South Korea, and Russia stumbled into crisis, culminating in
the collapse of hedge-fund giant Long-Term Capital Management (LTCM),
which played key roles in precipitating the crisis to begin with,
Greenspan moved to increase liquidity to support the distressed bond
markets. At the helm of LTCM was yet another former member of the Fed
board, ex-vice chairman David Mullins. Mullins was there to plead for
help from his former colleagues. When New York Fed president William
McDonough helped coordinate a bailout of LTCM at his offices, Greenspan
defended McDonough before a congressional oversight committee.
Reflecting on all the corporate welfare being doled out to prop up bad
private-sector investments worldwide, Bill Clinton appointee Alice
Rivlin, the able former congressional budget director, observed that
"the Fed was in a sense acting as the central banker of the world".
During Clinton's first term, Greenspan had handed the president a
"pro-incumbent-type economy" and was rewarded with a seat next to the
First Lady in Clinton's televised State of the Union address and a
third-term appointment as Fed chairman. Crony capitalism was in full
swing.
Short-term
currency swaps are repurchase-type agreements through which currencies
are exchanged. Mexico purchased dollars in exchange for pesos and
simultaneously agreed to sell dollars against pesos three months hence.
The US earned interest on its Mexican pesos at a specified rate.
Historically,
the US and Mexican economies have always been closely integrated in a
semi-colonial relationship. In 1994, the United States supplied 69
percent of Mexico's high-value-added imports and absorbed about 85
percent of its low-cost labor-intensive exports. US investors have
provided a substantial share of foreign investment in Mexico and have
established numerous manufacturing facilities there to take advantage
of low wages and unregulated labor and environmental regimes. Also, the
US has served as a large market for illegal Mexican immigrant labor in
its underground economy and farm sector, which has grown to be a
sizable foreign-currency earner for Mexico. Mexico has long been the
third-largest trading partner of the United States, accounting for 10
percent of US exports and about 8 percent of US imports in 1994. The
maquiladora assembly industry concentrated on the Mexican side of the
US-Mexico border was hailed by neo-liberals as a model of successful
free trade, instead of the sweatshop zone it actually was.
In
1994, under newly installed president Ernesto Zedillo, a Yale-educated
economist, Mexico entered the North American Free Trade Agreement with
the United States and Canada. NAFTA, conceived as a regional economic
counterweight to the EU, further opened Mexico to foreign investment
and bolstered investor interest on the hope that with NAFTA, Mexico's
long-term prospects for stable economic development were likely to
improve, at least for the benefit of foreign investors. NAFTA, as
negotiated and signed in December 1992 by the administrations of
Mexican president Carlos Salinas de Gortari and US president George
Bush Sr, and as amended and implemented by the Salinas and Clinton
administrations in 1993, did not offer Mexico any significant increase
in access to the US market. Rather, Mexico was blackmailed into signing
NAFTA to prevent Mexican businesses from being bankrupted wholesale by
sudden waves of pending US protectionism.
Mexico
was also advised by neo-liberals to adopt an exchange-rate system
intended to protect foreign investors who could exchange their peso
earnings for dollars at the Mexican central bank at an overvalued rate.
In 1988, the nominal exchange rate of the peso had been fixed
temporarily in relation to the US dollar. However, because the
inflation rate in Mexico was greater than that in the United States, a
peso nominal depreciation against the dollar was needed to keep the
real exchange rate of the peso from increasing. With the nominal
exchange rate of the peso fixed, the real exchange rate of the peso
appreciated during this period. In 1989, this fixed-exchange-rate
system was replaced by a "crawling peg" system, under which the
peso-dollar exchange rate was adjusted daily to allow a slow rate of
nominal depreciation of the peso to occur over time. In 1991, the
crawling peg was replaced with a band within which the peso was allowed
to fluctuate. The ceiling of the band was adjusted daily to permit some
appreciation of the dollar (depreciation of the peso) to occur. The
Mexican government used the exchange-rate system as an anchor for an
unsustainable economic policy, ie, as a way to reduce inflation through
shrinking the economy, to force a politically destabilizing fiscal
policy, and thus to provide a comfortable climate for foreign
investors, who managed to carry home the same dollars they brought in
via a short circuit, while leaving only their peso holdings behind that
the Mexican central banks had promised to guarantee as fully
convertible at an over-valued fixed exchange rate despite predictable
unsustainability.
Before
1994, Mexico's strategy of adopting sound monetary and austere fiscal
policies appeared to be having its intended effects of making foreign
capital feel secure while the Mexican economy was steadily being
hollowed out. Inflation had been steadily reduced by the inflated peso,
government social spending was down to reduce the budget deficit, and
foreign capital investment was increasing. Moreover, unlike in the
years before 1982, most foreign capital was flowing to Mexico's private
sector that yielded higher returns rather than as low-interest loans to
the Mexican government to finance budget deficits. Although Mexico was
experiencing a very large current-account deficit, both in absolute
terms and in relation to the size of its economy, neo-liberal policy
makers did not consider it an immediate problem. They pointed to
Mexico's large foreign-currency reserves, its rising exports, and its
seemingly endless ability to attract and retain foreign investment.
This attitude ignored the fact that true wealth was leaving Mexico
through the turning of peso assets into dollar assets, masked by a
Mexican stock-market bubble fueled by an over-valued peso.
Reality
finally unmasked the faulty neo-liberal theory by late 1994. Mexico's
financial crisis was the inevitable outcome of the growing
inconsistency between its monetary and fiscal policies, its
over-dependence on export for growth, and its exchange-rate system
pegged to the dollar. Partly because of an upcoming presidential
election, Mexican authorities were reluctant to take actions in the
spring and summer of 1994, such as raising interest rates or devaluing
the peso, that could have reduced this inconsistency. This structural
policy inconsistency was exacerbated by the government's response to
several economic and political events that created investor concerns
about the likelihood of a currency devaluation. In response to investor
concerns, the government issued large amounts of short-term,
dollar-indexed notes called tesobonos. By the beginning of
December 1994, Mexico had become particularly vulnerable to a financial
crisis because its foreign-exchange reserves had fallen to $12.5
billion while it had tesobono obligations of $30 billion
maturing in 1995.
A
country can respond to a current-account deficit in four ways:
1.
Attract more foreign capital denominated in dollars. The US does not
need to do this because of dollar hegemony, but Mexico, which could not
print dollars, thus was forced to attract more foreign capital
denominated in dollars with a Ponzi scheme of paying old capital with
new capital.
2.
Use foreign-exchange reserves to cover the deficit. The US can do this
by printing dollars, the reserve currency of choice, but Mexico could
not print dollars, only pesos, which put more pressure on the
peso-dollar exchange rate.
3.
Allow its currency to depreciate, thus making imports more expensive
and exports cheaper. But for deeply indebted Mexico, a depreciated peso
would make servicing existing foreign loans more expensive in peso
terms.
4.
Tighten monetary and/or fiscal policy to reduce the demand for all
goods, including imports, shrinking the economy.
A
country such as Mexico can only use (3) and (4), as most Asian
countries also found out in 1997.
It
was obvious that Mexico was experiencing a large current-account
deficit financed mostly by short-term portfolio capital that was
vulnerable to a sudden reversal of investor confidence. Nevertheless,
neo liberal policy makers in both Mexico and Washington, while
acknowledging that the peso was overvalued and the existing exchange
rate was unsustainable, were undecided about the extent to which the
peso was overvalued and if and when financial markets might force
Mexico to take action. Estimates of the overvaluation ranged between 5
and 20 percent. Moreover, Fed and Treasury officials under Alan
Greenspan and Robert Rubin respectively did not foresee the magnitude
of the crisis that eventually unfolded. The IMF was oblivious to the
seriousness of the situation that was developing in Mexico and, for
most of 1994, did not see a compelling case for a change in Mexico's
exchange-rate policy. In the period prior to July 1997, when the Asian
financial crises broke out first in Thailand, the IMF was praising
South Korea and most other Asian economies for its continuing growth
and sound exchange-rate policies. Even after financial contagion was in
full force, the IMF kept releasing complacent prognoses of the
temporary nature of the crisis as a passing liquidity crunch, while
denying its structural causes.
The
objectives of the US and IMF rescue packages for Mexico, after the
December 1994 devaluation and the subsequent loss of market confidence
in the peso, were (1) to help Mexico overcome its allegedly short-term
liquidity crisis and (2) to limit the adverse effects of Mexico's
crisis spreading to the economies of other emerging market nations and
beyond. No effort was directed at restructuring fundamental neo-liberal
policy faults, nor to admit that localized isolation is empty hope in a
globalized system.
Many
observers opposed any US financial rescue to Mexico. They argued that tesobono
investors should not be shielded from financial losses on moral-hazard
grounds, and that neither the danger posed by the spread of Mexico's
crisis to other nations nor the risk to US trade, employment, and
immigration was sufficient to justify such bailout.
The
Bank of Mexico, the central bank, increased the interest rate from 9
percent to 18 percent on short-term, peso-denominated Mexican
government notes, called cetes, in an attempt to stem the
outflow of capital. However, despite higher interest rates, investor
demand for cetes continued to lag. Investors were demanding
even higher interest rates on newly issued cetes because of
their perception that the peso would be subject to progressively larger
devaluation by rising interest rates. It was a classic vicious circle.
Options available to the Mexican government at this time included (1)
offering even higher interest rates on cetes; (2) reducing
government expenditures to reduce domestic demand, decrease imports,
and relieve pressure on the peso; or (3) devaluing the peso. All three
options would lead to increased downward pressure on the peso and the
economy. The only workable option, exchange control in the form of
restrictive capital flow, was not considered by the
Harvard-Yale-trained Mexican central bankers, nor encouraged by US
advisors. It was not until 1998, when Malaysia successfully adopted
exchange control, that some born-again market-failure fundamentalists,
led by MIT economist Paul Krugman, grudging acknowledged it as a
legitimate option.
From
the perspective of the Mexican authorities, the first two choices were
unattractive in a presidential-election year because they could have
led to a significant downturn in economic activity and could have
further weakened Mexico's banking system. The third choice,
devaluation, was also unattractive, since Mexico's success in
attracting substantial new foreign investment to feed its Ponzi scheme
depended on its commitment to maintain a stable exchange rate. In
addition, a stable exchange rate had been an essential ingredient of
long-standing policy agreements among government, labor, and business,
and these agreements were perceived as ensuring economic and social
stability. Also, the stable exchange rate was considered a key to
continued reductions in the inflation rate by orthodox neo-classical
economics. Ironically, typical of all Ponzi schemes, success was fatal
because it accelerated unsustainability.
Rather
than adopting any of these options, the government chose, in the spring
of 1994, to increase its issuance of tesobonos. Because tesobonos
were dollar-indexed, holders could avoid losses that would otherwise
result if Mexico subsequently chose to devalue its currency. The
government promised to repay investors an amount, in pesos, sufficient
to protect the dollar value of their investment. Tesobono
financing in effect dollarized Mexican sovereign debt and transferred
foreign-exchange risk from investors to the Mexican central bank and
government and to provide a short-term liquidity solution that would
exacerbate long-term structural problems. Tesobonos proved
attractive to domestic and foreign investors. However, as sales of tesobonos
rose, Mexico became vulnerable to a financial market crisis because
many tesobono purchasers were portfolio investors who were very
sensitive to changes in interest rates and related risks. Furthermore, tesobonos
had short maturities, which meant that their holders might not roll
them over if investors perceived (1) an increased risk of a government
default or (2) higher returns elsewhere. Market discipline operated
like a pool of circling hungry sharks.
Nevertheless,
Mexican authorities viewed tesobono financing as the best way
to stabilize foreign-exchange reserves over the short term and to avoid
the immediate costs implicit in the other alternatives. In fact,
Mexico's foreign-exchange reserves did stabilize at a level of about
$17 billion from the end of April through August 1994, when the
presidential elections came to a conclusion. Mexican authorities
expected that investor confidence would be restored after the August
presidential election and that investment flows would return in
sufficient amounts to preclude any need for continued, large-scale tesobono
financing.
After
the election, however, foreign-investment flows did not recover to the
extent expected by Mexican authorities, in part because peso interest
rates were allowed to decline in August and were maintained at that
level until December. During the autumn of 1994, it became increasingly
clear that Mexico's mix of monetary, fiscal, and exchange-rate policies
needed to be adjusted. The current-account deficit had worsened during
the year, partly as a result of the strengthening of the economy
related to a moderate pre-election loosening of fiscal policy,
including a step up in development lending, which was considered by
market fundamentalists as a big no-no. Imports had also surged as the
peso became further overvalued. Mexico had become heavily exposed to a
run on its foreign-exchange reserves as a result of substantial tesobono
financing. Outstanding tesobono obligations increased from $3.1
billion at the end of March to $29.2 billion in December. Also, between
January and November 1994, US three-month Treasury bill yields had
risen from 3.04 percent to 5.45 percent, substantially increasing the
attractiveness of US government securities. In the middle of November
1994, Mexican authorities had to draw down foreign-currency reserves to
meet the demand for dollars.
On
November 15, 1994, in response to US domestic economic conditions, the
Fed raised the federal funds rate by three-quarters of a percentage
point to 5.5 percent, raising the general level of dollar interest
rates and further increasing the attractiveness of US bonds to
investors. By late November and early December, poor economic
performance spilled over to political incidents that caused
apprehension among investors regarding Mexico's political stability.
These concerns were compounded on December 9, when the new Mexican
administration revealed that it expected an even higher current-account
deficit in 1995 but planned no change in its exchange-rate policy. This
decision led to a further loss in confidence by investors, increased
redemptions of Mexican securities, and a significant drop in
foreign-exchange reserves to $10 billion. Meanwhile, Mexico's
outstanding tesobono obligations reached $30 billion, all
coming due in 1995. However, Mexican government officials continued to
assure investors that the peso would not be devalued.
On
December 20, Mexican authorities sought to relieve pressure on the
exchange rate by announcing a widening of the peso-dollar exchange-rate
band. The widening of the band in effect devalued the peso by about 15
percent. However, the government did not announce any new fiscal or
monetary measures to accompany the devaluation - such as raising
interest rates. This inaction was accompanied by more than $4 billion
in losses in foreign reserves on December 21 and, on December 22,
Mexico was forced to float its currency freely. The discrepancy between
the stated exchange-rate policy of the Mexican government throughout
most of 1994 and its devaluation of the peso on December 20, along with
a failure to announce appropriate accompanying economic-policy
measures, contributed to a significant loss of investor confidence in
the newly elected government and growing fear that default was
imminent.
Consequently,
downward pressure on the peso continued. By early January 1995,
investors realized that tesobono redemptions could soon exhaust
Mexico's reserves and, in the absence of external assistance, that
Mexico might default on its dollar-indexed and dollar-denominated debt.
As
1994 began, signs were visible that Mexico was vulnerable to
speculative attacks on the peso and that its large and growing
current-account deficit and its exchange-rate policy might not be
sustainable. However, neo-liberal economists generally thought that
Mexico's economy was characterized by "sound economic fundamentals" and
that, with the major economic reforms of the past decade along
Washington Consensus lines, Mexico had laid an adequate foundation for
economic growth in the long term. In reality, Mexico was exporting real
wealth and importing hot money with the help of a flawed central-bank
policy that was attracting large capital inflows and held substantial
foreign-exchange reserves derived from foreign debt. Concerns about the
viability of Mexico's exchange-rate system increased after the
assassination of presidential candidate Luis Donaldo Colosio in the
latter part of March and the subsequent drawdown of about $10 billion
in foreign-exchange reserves by the end of April. Just after the
assassination, US Treasury and Fed officials temporarily enlarged
long-standing currency-swap facilities with Mexico from $1 billion to
$6 billion. These enlarged facilities were made permanent with the
establishment of the North American Financial Group in April. The
initiative to enlarge the swap facilities permanently preceded the
Colosio assassination. Mexican foreign-exchange reserves stabilized at
about $17 billion by the end of April 1994.
At
the end of June 1994, a new run on the peso was under way. Between June
21 and July 22, foreign-exchange reserves were drawn down by nearly $3
billion, to about $14 billion. In early July, Mexico asked the Fed and
Treasury to explore with the central banks of certain European
countries the establishment of a contingency, short-term swap facility.
That facility could be used in conjunction with the US-Mexican swap
facility to help Mexico cope with possible exchange-rate volatility in
the period leading up to the August election. By July, staff in the Fed
had concluded that Mexico's exchange rate probably was overvalued and
that some sort of adjustment eventually would be needed. However, US
officials thought that Mexican officials might be correct in hoping
that foreign capital inflows could resume after the August elections.
In August, the US and the BIS established the requested swap facility,
but not until US officials had secured an oral understanding with
Mexico that it would adjust its exchange-rate system if pressure on the
peso continued after the election. The temporary facility incorporated
the US-Mexican $6 billion swap arrangement established in April. At the
end of July, pressure on the peso abated, and Mexican foreign-exchange
reserves increased to more than $16 billion. Significant new pressure
on the peso did not develop immediately after the August election, but
at the same time, capital inflows did not return to their former
levels.
The
Fed and Treasury did not foresee the serious consequences that an
abrupt devaluation would have on investor confidence in Mexico. These
included a possible wholesale flight of capital that could bring Mexico
to the point of default and, in the judgment of US and IMF officials,
require a major financial assistance package. IMF officials thought
that Mexico's sizable exports meant there was not a need to adjust the
foreign-exchange policy. They did not foresee the exchange-rate crisis
and, for most of 1994, did not see a compelling case for a change in
Mexico's exchange-rate policy. The IMF completed an annual review of
Mexico's foreign-exchange and economic policies in February 1994. The
review did not identify problems with Mexico's exchange-rate policy.
This pattern of IMF complacency was repeated in Asia and Latin America
throughout the rest of the decade.
Whereas
the 1982 rescue package would turn out to be just the beginning of a
protracted process of managing Mexico's excessive indebtedness,
including several concerted debt-rescheduling exercises, a debt
buy-back, and the 1990 debt-reduction agreement negotiated under the
terms of the Brady Plan, the 1995 rescue package worked better. After
the 1982 rescue package, Mexico received support from the Fed and the
Treasury on three other occasions, but always in the form of interim
financing while other workouts were concluded. The difference between
the 1982 and 1995 packages is that while the former was followed by a
decade of living in "exile" from the international capital markets, the
latter was successful in quickly restoring market access. The
difference in outcomes must be related to the size of the financial
package and its medium-term quality. In 1995 the financial rescue
package was designed to be large enough plausibly to solve Mexico's
liquidity crisis; in 1982, the package was large enough to avoid a
Mexican default but for the next six years the country had to go from
one rescheduling exercise to another, with the uncertainty of whether
the country would be able to meet its obligations always lurking on the
horizon. Success in the 1995 package was not applicable to correcting
Mexico's fundamental debt problem.
In
1995, after the Federal Reserve started to hike interest rates in 1994
and sharply curtailed its own purchase of Treasury bills, triggering
the Mexico peso crisis and a subsequent US slowdown, the Bank of Japan
initiated a program to buy $100 billion of US treasuries. China bought
$80 billion. Hong Kong and Singapore bought $22 billion each. South
Korea, Malaysia, Thailand, Indonesia and the Philippines bought $30
billion. The Asian purchase totaled $260 billion from 1994-97, the
entire increase in foreign-held US dollar reserves. These recycled
dollars pushed up stock prices in the United States.
Like
the rest of the world, Asia is heavily dependent on export to the
United States. Japan, by far the largest Asian economy, is paralyzed by
an export addiction for dollars that are useless in Japan. This
paralysis is made worse by an institutionally based policy dispute
between the Ministry of Finance and the Bank of Japan, its newly
installed central bank, in dealing with its economic woes. The dispute
centers on the nature of the Japanese banking system and its
traditional national banking role in supporting the export-based
national economic policy. Central banking, as espoused by BIS
regulations, challenges the very root of Japanese political-economy
culture, which has never viewed reform as a license to weaken Japanese
nationalism that saved Japan from Western imperialism in the 19th
century. The Japanese model, until it became captured by Japanese
militarism, provided inspiration for nationalist movements all over
Asia against Western imperialism. After 1979, central banking has been
viewed increasingly as the monetary institution of financial
neo-liberalism, which has become synonymous with economic
neo-imperialism.
In
the US and EU, fiscal policy was significantly diminished as a
macroeconomic policy tool in the 1990s, releasing the Fed and the ECB
to assume the role of meta-political economic manager for their
societies. Money, instead of an engine of commerce for the benefit of
people, has become an economic icon whose sanctity must be defended
with human casualties for the good of the increasingly
internationalized financial system. Unregulated global financial
markets operating within the context of international monetary anarchy
allows these two key central banks to impact economic growth adversely,
first in the rest of the world, now even in their home countries. When
the Fed moved to tighten monetary policy in 1999-2000, after a panic
ease in 1997-99, it in effect suppressed global economic growth by
forcing the ECB and other central banks into a series of parallel rate
hikes designed to support the value of their currencies against the
dominant dollar. With joblessness rising and growth restrained around
the world, pressure mounted on the United States to expand its already
unsustainable current-account deficit, to the inevitable detriment of
many US households and businesses, particular in the manufacturing
sector but increasingly in the information and data-processing sectors
as well. The so-called New Economy died. The Fed, the ECB and most
other central banks have remained uniquely opaque entities. In fact,
the Fed takes pride in playing cat-and-mouse games with the market over
the prospect of its interest-rate policy and allows the financial
market to operate like a lottery, with the winner being the lucky one
who correctly guessed its interest-rate decisions. Most Asian central
banks follow reactively Fed policy and action.
Bill
Gross, manager director of Pimco, the largest bond-investment fund in
the United States, may not have a monopoly on truth, but he controls
vast investment power over the credit market and makes decisions based
on his views. He wrote recently that 13 percent of the US stock market,
35 percent of the US Treasury market, 23 percent of the US corporate
bond market, and 14 percent direct ownership in US companies are now in
the hands of non-US investors. And with the trade deficit at 6 percent
of GDP and the US need to attract nearly 80 percent of all the world's
ongoing savings just to keep the dollar at current levels, "an end to
the party is clearly in sight". Gross said that former Treasury
secretary Robert Rubin's policy of a strong dollar succeeded so
famously that US bonds and stocks now have lower yields and much higher
price-to-earnings ratios (P/Es) than most alternative markets. This
strong-dollar policy, implemented through the Fed under Alan Greenspan,
has painted the US into a corner from which either a falling dollar,
depreciating financial markets, or both are "nearly inevitable".
The
net foreign debt in the US economy is now 22 percent of GDP. Assuming
an economic recovery, the US economy is on a trajectory toward a debt
burden of 40 percent of GDP within five years, roughly the debt-to-GDP
ratio of Argentina in 2000. What keeps the US afloat is dollar
hegemony. The US cannot forever borrow in order to buy more from the
rest of the world than it sells. The interest burden will eventually be
so heavy that foreign investors will be unwilling or unable to keep
financing this rising debt. When that happens, the dollar will drop and
dollar interest rates will spike upward. The United States will then be
forced to run a trade surplus with a drastic devaluation of the dollar
and/or a draconian deflation in real incomes in order to reduce demand
for imports and make US goods cheap enough to run a surplus in world
markets. Yet this will directly shrink world trade, making it difficult
for the US to reduce its cumulated debt.
The
costs of balancing trade through deflation would be near fatal.
According to one calculation (Godley 1995), bringing a current-account
deficit of 2 percent GDP into balance would require a 10 percent drop
in GDP and a jump of 5 percent in the unemployment rate. With today's
trade deficit of 4 percent and rising, the required contraction in GDP
would be 20 percent or greater and an unemployment rate of an
additional 10 percent to the current 7 percent. Attempting to regain
balance through currency devaluation could be catastrophic.
Goldman-Sachs recently estimated that it would take a more than 40
percent drop in the dollar just to halve the US current-account
deficit. Getting to a trade balance will be even more difficult because
US manufacturing capacity may well have shrunk below the level needed
to eliminate the trade deficit through expanding exports. Given
relentless import competition, investors are reluctant to make
long-term capital available to small and medium manufacturing firms,
and some large ones as well. The grim outlook for manufacturing also
reduces the incentive for young people to invest in becoming skilled
manufacturing workers.
The
low savings rate in the United States also contributes to the
current-account problem but it is now a function of a deficiency in
private rather than public savings. This is a much harder problem to
solve. In fact, the US does not seem to know how to raise its private
savings rate without putting a damper on its relentless push on
expanding consumer finance. Under current conditions, increasing the
savings rate would reduce consumer demand, upon which the US economy
and the world depend.
Japan's
economic problem is rooted in the geopolitical shift resulting from the
end of the Cold War. The Japanese economy has outgrown its postwar role
as an export engine. With the end of the Cold War, Japan no longer
enjoys geopolitically induced special trade concessions from the United
States. The continuing trade surplus with the US is now contingent on
its being recycled into dollar assets. Not only will the continued
expansion of export to the US not be sustainable at a rate that will
help the doomed Japanese domestic economy, but even effective
stimulation of domestic consumption cannot solve the Japanese dilemma
because the domestic economy is too small to sustain the enormous and
growing overcapacity of its export engine. The Japanese economy cannot
be revived by domestic restructuring unless it is prepared to shrink
drastically to the size of the United Kingdom. No monetary or fiscal
measures can overcome this structural problem, which is the legacy of
policies of General Douglas MacArthur's occupation after World War II.
The Japanese problem is not a purely economic problem. It is a
political-economy problem. What Japan needs is to restructure its
international economic relationships away from its unnatural partner,
the United States, toward its natural partner, China, and to shift from
an export economy to a regional-developmental economy.
The
anchor of US policy in Asia is the United States' "special
relationship" to Japan. The intensity and bitterness of the historical
conflict between Japan and the US for their separate interests in Asia
have not been eliminated by the post-World War II facade of "special
relationship" or by the Mutual Defense Treaty. Before World War II,
Japan, not China, was seen by most US leaders as America's chief rival
in Asia. They squeezed Japan's access to vital raw materials,
particularly oil, and so obstructed Japan's plan of becoming a great
regional power through its conquest of a fragmented China weakened by a
century of Western imperialism. While the targets of Japanese expansion
in World War II were primarily the colonies of the British and French
empires, the sole exception being the Philippines, the objective made
it necessary for Japan to disable the US Pacific Fleet. The Pacific
theater against Japan in World War II was won mainly by US efforts,
unlike the European theater, where Britain and the Soviet Union also
played major roles. It was the Japanese attack on Pearl Harbor that
forced Adolf Hitler to declare war on a formally neutral United States,
thus saving Britain from imminent defeat. It was one of the two
strategic errors Germany made, the other being the invasion of the
Soviet Union. Without a two-front war that eventually destroyed the
German 6th Army on Russian soil in February 1943 and the relentless
Soviet counteroffensive afterward that tied up half of German military
assets, it would be doubtful whether the US landing in Normandy in 1944
would have been as successful as it was.
Britain,
in winning a Pyrrhic victory against Germany with US and Soviet help,
lost both empire and greatness. Together with Britain, supposedly the
winner, Japan and Germany, the vanquished, were thrown by World War II
into the arms of the United States as suppliants, in a subordination
masked by the euphemism of "special relationships". Postwar Germany,
divided into socialist East and capitalist West, benefited economically
from the Cold War by the need of the US to subsidize West Germany to
keep it safely in the Western camp. Outside of imposed anti-Sovietism
and anti-communism, West Germany enjoyed enviable autonomy from US
policy domination. Japan enjoyed much less autonomy than West Germany,
a fact many Japanese resented as US racism. Further, Germany had a real
historical phobia against a powerful Russia pushing westward, while
Japan had less real reason to fear China, or an Soviet Union that was
fundamentally Europe-oriented. Japan had already defeated Russia once.
After
the Japanese surrender, MacArthur at first aimed at restructuring
Japanese politics and economics to prevent a return to militarism. For
that purpose, MacArthur's occupation regime purged from Japanese
politics all wartime leaders, instituted land reform, and began
breaking down large corporate conglomerates (zaibatsu or keiretsu),
in favor of populist if not socialist forces. This strategy would begin
to change in the early months of 1948 with what would be labeled in
diplomatic history as "The Reverse Course".
As
fears of Soviet expansion grew in Washington, concerns also grew that
MacArthur's reform program was making Japan geopolitically unreliable,
ideologically unstable, economically weak, and geopolitically
vulnerable to subversive infiltration or, in the longer run, perhaps
even military invasion with Fifth Column help. As China liberated
itself by establishing a socialist state in 1949, MacArthur was ordered
to turn US occupation policy abruptly into a strategy of keeping Japan
from turning toward socialist paths. Since Japan was viewed as a
"strong point" by key US grand strategists George Kennan, George
Marshall, and Dean Acheson, a more politically regressive and
economically conservative program was put into place. It was a program
designed to stabilize the Japanese political economy and to set the
stage for revived limited Japanese military strength in the future that
would assist US efforts in countering international communism in Japan
and the rest of East Asia.
To
support this controlled military power, a US trade subsidy/preference
regime for Japan was instituted. MacArthur, who had all but set himself
up as the new emperor of Japan and who had built a postwar popularity
within US domestic politics, criticizing the State Department for
shortcomings ranging from Eurocentrism to excessive meddling in the
Pacific to lack of political will to use nuclear weapons on China,
would argue not only against reversing the anti-zaibatsu
program, but also against strengthening the Japanese military from whom
he had suffered well-publicized defeat with deep personal
embarrassment. Ironically, it was left to the Supreme Military
Commander/Occupier to argue that economic growth and a stable political
order were the most important weapons in the struggle for containment
of the communist threat for Japan, not the creation of military might.
Nobody
doubted the general's argument about the importance of economic
strength and political stability, but many at the US Defense Department
and some even at the State Department subsequently insisted that they
wanted a major portion of the fruits of US supplied economic revival to
be channeled into Japanese military strengthening. In their minds,
Japan should accept a significant share of the burden of defending
itself and containing communism in the region. This position would win
the debate in Washington and would be presented to Japanese authorities
in 1950-51 by president Harry Truman's special envoy, John Foster
Dulles. In the 1950s, the administrations of Truman and Dwight D
Eisenhower both believed that open tolerance of Japanese resistance to
US imports, systematic undervaluation of the yen, and total reliance on
US military protection were necessary to strengthen Japan domestically
and legitimize it internationally as a solid anti-communist ally. After
persistent persuasion by premier Yoshida Shigeru, US leaders also
decided that pushing the Japanese government too soon and too hard to
build up its military significantly merely to reduce the US defense
burden could lead to a popular backlash in Japan that might threaten
the budding alliance and, by association, the maintenance of US
military bases in Japan.
Japan,
a recent and very bitter enemy, was clearly not sharing much of the
cost burden of the anti-communist alliance early in the Cold War. In
fact, it worked to benefit economically from it. The kernel of this
dilemma is still alive in the developing relationship of new US-Japan
relationship under the current administration of President George W
Bush. While the Bush Team claims a continuation of the strong-dollar
policy, there is much open talk of coordinated government intervention
against a yen devaluation beyond 120 to the dollar. Concerned about the
acceptance of the US-Japan alliance in domestic US politics, US leaders
decided they must maintain US dominance of the political alliance in
exchange for generous US aid, trade, and military protection policies
Washington had already granted to Tokyo. As the sole economic power
that had directly profited from World War II, the United States had the
resources and the confidence to buy Japanese support with economic
carrots. In particular, Yoshida would be pushed to accept Washington's
pro-Kuomintang (KMT, or Nationalist) and tough anti-communist China
policies. US elites worried that if Yoshida diverged too strongly from
the anti-communist strategies being advocated by the United States,
Congress and the public would demand a fundamental reconsideration of
the already controversial one-way economic relationship. The same
argument was presented to other national leaders around the world as a
reason for them to shun independent national-policy lines toward the
communist world. The geopolitical foundation of the Marshall Plan was
obvious, but the US domestic-politics argument was the classic mantra.
Yet
the cost for Japan of compliance with US geopolitical leadership
demands was very high because the United States had adopted such a
tough policy toward China, with which Japan would have preferred to
have closer economic and diplomatic ties than intransigent US policy
would allow. This problem exists even today, albeit under different
geopolitical conditions. The Truman administration's need to guarantee
domestic consensus for its domestically controversial early-Cold War
grand strategy often compelled it to abandon its privately preferred
economic and diplomatic strategies toward China. In 1949-50, the US
refused to abandon KMT leader Chiang Kai-shek and recognize the new
People's Republic of China (PRC), despite Truman's personal disdain for
Chiang and KMT corruption and Madam Chiang's deft manipulation of the
Republican right wing and the anti-communist Christian fundamentalists
in US domestic politics.
At
the outbreak of the Korean War, the Truman administration reversed
earlier statements of neutrality regarding the Chinese Civil War and
sent the 7th Fleet to protect KMT-controlled Taiwan from potential
forceful unification with the communist mainland. This locked the
United States into an exclusive diplomatic relationship with Chiang's
regime until 1973, and the 7th Fleet continues to be active in the
Taiwan Strait today. The Taiwan issue remains the main obstacle to
normal US-China relations. After the late-1950 escalation of the Korean
War, a desperate Truman administration applied a total embargo on
China, and policies more hostile than those applied to the Soviet Union
(this imbalance in the Coordinating Committee for Multilateral Export
Controls - CoCom - regime would come to be known as the "China
Differential").
Many
of the US diplomatic and trade policies around the world, particularly
in Asia, were often viewed by top presidential advisors as ineffective
or even counterproductive on geopolitical grounds, but politically
unavoidable on domestic grounds, particularly after the outbreak and
escalation of the Korean War from June-November 1950.
To
understand the sacrifice Tokyo had to make in order to grant the United
States a firm leadership role on the budding US-Japan alliance's China
policy, it is critical to note just how important the Chinese economy
had been to Japan in modern history. It was the search for a preferred
integrated economic relationship with China that fueled Japanese
aggression on the mainland in the 1930s. Japanese leadership was
actually obsessed first and foremost with the threat from the Soviet
Union and the lessons of World War I about the need for an autarkic
economy to provide staying power in war. The quest for Japanese autarky
on the Asian mainland helped drive Japan deeper and deeper into a
quagmire in China and, eventually, into war with the United States over
oil supply. In the 1920s and for most of the 1930s, China (including
Manchuria) was by far Japan's biggest export market and import provider
in the region. Japanese exploitation of Chinese resources financed the
Japanese military machine for World War II. In 1949, Yoshida and other
members of the Japanese elite saw real economic and political benefits
in establishing relations with the new communist regime in Beijing.
Postwar Japan wanted to appear sympathetic to the new Asian
post-colonial nationalist movements, a theme of the wartime
Co-prosperity Ring.
The
problem was not that PRC-Japan trade was viewed as against US or
Japanese national interests, but that it was unacceptable to US
domestic politics. In February and March 1949, six months before the
founding of the People's Republic, the US National Security Council
produced NSC 41, a report on China trade policy. The document reflected
a cautious faith in the possibility of Chinese Titoism and the
usefulness of US trade with areas held by the Chinese Communist Party
as a way to reduce the CCP's dependence on Moscow. The sections on
Sino-Japan trade were, in a sense, more practical, emphasizing the goal
of reducing the US burden of rebuilding Japan as well as gaining some
degree of political leverage over China through trade dependence with
Japan. The State Department was hardly indifferent to the concerns
raised by opponents to Sino-Japanese trade, so NSC 41 and other
directives advised MacArthur to encourage trade on a quid pro quo basis
and to try to find alternative markets and raw-material sources
elsewhere in Asia to reduce Japanese dependence on China for critical
materials. The need for such alternative markets for Japan was one of
the arguments Washington used on Japan to secure its support for
keeping Southeast Asia out of communist hands early in the Cold War.
This constituted another "Reverse Course", in which the United States
went from a critic to a supporter of European imperialism in British
Malaya and Indochina.
Despite
US restrictions, Japanese trade with mainland China grew tenfold from
1947-50. The Korean War and the US-led embargoes against China halted
this trend. Another problem facing the United States in its calculation
about US-China and US-Japan trade was that, for economic and political
reasons, Britain was unwilling to apply the strict export-control
measures toward China that Washington demanded, fearing the damage such
measures would do to British Hong Kong. In November 1949, top US
officials recognized that if Western Europe traded relatively normally
with China while the United States and Japan embargoed it, this would
only serve to increase the expense of the US relationship with Japan
without any real costs being raised to the Chinese economy. Although
the Truman administration would continue to try to prevent China from
getting strategically important materials (1A and 1B items on the CoCom
list), it seemed resigned to allow PRC trade with the US and Japan on a
"cash basis". The logical standard was that the same criteria should be
applied to China that were being applied to the Soviet Union and
Eastern Europe. In the first half of 1950, the picture became more
mixed as relations with Beijing worsened after the January seizure of
US consular property and the February signing of the Sino-Soviet
defense treaty. The United States wanted to find a balance between, on
the one hand, reducing the burden on the Japanese economy (and,
indirectly, on the United States) by allowing trade between Japan and
the PRC, and, on the other, reducing Japanese dependence on China,
which could provide China with political leverage over Tokyo and
threaten US dominance.
The
Truman administration pushed this argument particularly hard on other
non-communist partners in East Asia, which had been reluctant to open
up their economies to their former Japanese occupiers. The
administration argued that increasing their trade with Japan was a
necessary role for these allies since Japan's natural market in China
had fallen to the communists. The Korean War would radically alter this
picture, with the US leveling the "China Differential" in CoCom. It was
clear that domestic politics, rather than the "high politics" of
strategy, was driving US trade policy toward China, as was true with
the US attitude toward Chinese accession to the World Trade
Organization five decades later. This all but destroyed Sino-Japanese
trade, as some 400 items were put on the list of prohibited products.
Over the next several years, important elites, including president
Eisenhower himself, recognized the illogic of the China Differential
and a strict Japanese embargo on China. But significant relaxation of
China-Japan trade restrictions would remain in place until well after
the end of the Korean War.
Throughout
1951, John Foster Dulles, Truman's envoy to Japan for negotiations on
the Japanese Peace Treaty, would apply the same logic with Yoshida
Shigeru. Dulles made various arguments why Japan should reject Beijing
as a diplomatic partner, continue recognizing Chiang Kai-shek's regime
on Taiwan as the sole legitimate government of all of China, and sign a
peace treaty with Chiang's Republic of China rather than the PRC.
Dulles also sought Yoshida's general compliance with US limits on trade
contacts with the PRC.
Like
most Japanese elites since MacArthur, Yoshida was anti-communist. But
as a practical matter, Japan wanted diplomatic ties with Beijing and
much more extensive trade relations than Dulles's preferred scenario
would allow. Yoshida bluntly put it: "I don't care whether China is red
or green. China is a natural market, and it has become necessary for
Japan to think about markets."
In
his effort to persuade Japanese leaders, Dulles' trump card was not a
geostrategic argument but a domestic political one. He emphasized that
if Japan did not comply with US general Cold War strategy, the military
protection of Japan by US forces would become more controversial
domestically, as would economic aid and Japan's preferential trade and
financial arrangements. It was this domestic political argument, above
all others, that convinced the reluctant Japanese that questioning the
US leadership role in the Cold War in Asia could carry devastating
results for the maverick nation's security and economic interests.
Dulles would return to this tried-and-true bargaining tactic again as
president Eisenhower's Secretary of State in order to prevent Japan
from establishing politically significant trade offices in China. The
result of Japan's acquiescence to US demands, the December 1951 Yoshida
Letter and subsequent bilateral Peace Treaty negotiations with Taipei
in 1952, locked Japan into a pro-Taiwan, anti-Beijing diplomatic
posture for the next 21 years. With Japanese acquiescence to America's
harsh economic sanctions regime against China, the small-scale but
promising trade between Japan and the PRC allowed by the US in 1949-50
practically disappeared.
Politicians
are probably held in as low esteem in Japan today as in the United
States. For an Asian culture, that is a serious development.
Unfortunately, the bureaucracy, which basically sets policy for Japan,
is also not trusted because of the present anemic state of the economy
and US media scapegoating. After a whole decade of slow growth, the
streets of Tokyo still do not look like those of a poor economy,
because the Japanese government has been effectively insulating the
Japanese public from the real pain. The US had a cozy relationship with
the Liberal Democratic Party but had a contentious relationship over
trade. Today, young people in Japan are more openly nationalistic than
the subdued older generation. It will be increasingly more difficult
for the United States to work with Japan as time passes.
For
many years, Japan has counted on its economic strength to provide its
regional and global influence. There was one magic moment when the yen
was 79 to a US dollar and the Japanese economy on a currency basis was
larger than the US economy and Herman Khan was predicting the Japanese
Century. The psychological shock in shifting from a position of a
rising economic powerhouse to a situation where the world is
criticizing Japan's economy has sapped Japan's self-confidence. Market
capitalization of Japanese equity fell from 50 percent of global value
to just 10 percent, even as the US lost 60 percent of its peak market
capitalization. The economic difficulties Japan is experiencing are not
a banking problem, as US neo-liberal economists keep saying. The
central bank, though newly created, has become part of the problem. But
the central problem involves a much broader system of a dual economy of
successful transnational companies built on subsidiaries and networks
of other small companies that are operating along unique Japanese
relationships.
The
Finance Ministry, trying to help consumers by dropping the discount
rate to 0 percent, failed to help consumers but decimated the insurance
industry because it offered a guaranteed rate of return on its pension
plans that are now much higher than current returns on investment. The
industry could not find any place to put the money to provide the
return it had guaranteed. Large insurance companies went broke and the
people counting on them for their pensions no longer had pensions. As a
result, people started not renewing their policies.
Japan
is becoming an older society faster than any society in the world. But
it has a large savings base, about $10 trillion, which amounts to about
a per capita amount of $80,000, enough to cover per capita debt in the
United States at its height. But 60 percent of that money is held by
people over 65 who are not robust consumers. How does one motivate such
an economy? The world has never seen a country with a population this
old.
The
world consensus is pushing Japan into a quick solution so as to avoid
an even more traumatic Asian financial crisis. The concern in Tokyo is
that, if Japan did "fix" the economy in a hurry, it might cause more
trouble than would a gradual approach. The US has told Japan to lead.
The first solution Japan came up with when the Asian economy started to
collapse was a $100 billion security fund to help Asian economies,
which the US rejected. Economic growth has been flat since the
real-estate and stock bubble burst in 1990, except for 1996, when real
GDP growth was 3.6 percent due to a large fiscal stimulus and low
interest rates. Japan remains a massive net exporter of goods to the
rest of the world as its economy sinks. It has emerged as a model for
other Asian economies to avoid, rather than copy.
Japan,
as an Asian culture, places importance on the national economy and
operates as if individuals and companies can only prosper if the
national economy prospers. The US economy operates as a "natural"
calculus of individual survival. To Americans and American
corporations, a national economic boom has no meaning unless the
individual unit first benefits. As markets globalize, this creates
problems for management in both cultural regimes. For Japan, bailouts
are normal, while in the US bailouts, though they occur, are exercised
with apologies. When in trouble, the US economy historically sacrifices
quickly the weak and the small, while the Japanese economy punishes the
strong and big gradually.
When
the long-overdue US recession hits, Americans will see their faith in
market free enterprise shaken as the Japanese have been losing their
faith in their command economy, despite the fact that the government
has been reasonably effective in insulating the Japanese public from
economic pain. The Campaign 2000 rhetoric in the United States was
already slightly populist and the recession has yet to begin. The
recent Bush tax plan was couched in heavy populist rhetoric. The
problem is that around the world there are visible signs of exhaustion.
Asia and Latin America are completely worn out after six years of
tumult. The US boom was fed mostly by global deflation, and there have
not been free lunches even in the US. Even those who are still doing
well have to work 14-hour days and most families need to be two-income
households to make do. The press has stop running stories about people
with $60,000 annual incomes living in their cars in Silicon Valley
because it is no longer news. At this rate, unemployment may even come
as a relief and a guiltless way to get off the treadmill.
There
was a moment in the late 1960s, before the Vietnam War blew away all of
America's surpluses, that people with good incomes were beginning to
take three-day weekends on a regular year-around basis and eight-week
vacations. From Los Angeles to Dallas to Scarsdale, fathers were home
by 5:30pm barbecuing for the whole family and mothers had time for
their children, and the GDP was a mere $200 billion. Economists thought
then that if the GDP reached $1 trillion, all economic problems would
be solved. Instead, the GDP is now more than $10 trillion, and there is
financial crisis everywhere - from health care to social security to
education, even defense. There appears to be a problem with what growth
really is.
Next: The
Japanese Experience
|