Chinese
Currency
PART 1: Follies of fiddling with the yuan
By
Henry C K Liu
This article appeared in AToL on
October 23, 2004
Dollar hegemony
emerged after 1971 from the peculiar phenomenon of a fiat dollar not
backed by gold or any other species of value, continuing to assume the
status of the world's main reserve currency because of the US's
geopolitical supremacy. Such currency hegemony has become a key
dysfunctionality in the international finance architecture driving the
unregulated global financial markets in the past two decades. China's
overheated economy is the result of hot money inflow caused by dollar
hegemony. China's developing economy should be able to absorb huge
amounts of capital inflow, but dollar hegemony limits foreign
investment to only the Chinese export sector, where dollar revenue can
be earned to repay capital denominated in dollars. Since China's export
sector cannot grow faster than the import demands of other nations,
excessive dollar capital inflow overheats the export and
exported-related sectors, while other sectors of the Chinese economy
suffer acute capital shortage.
Overheated economies
produce growth-inhibiting inflation through
excessive import of money and sudden rises in prices for imported
commodities and energy. The imported inflation is then re-exported,
causing inflation in other parts of the global economy. Inflation
causes interest rates to rise, which in turn causes unemployment and
recession in all economies that are plagued by it.
China's currency,
known as the renminbi (RMB) yuan, has been pegged to
a fiat dollar within a narrow band (0.3%) around an official rate of
8.28 to 1 since 1995. Even though the yuan is still not entirely freely
convertible, any change in dollar interest rates will impact yuan
interest rates due to the peg.
While the linkage
between exchange rate and interest rate is direct,
the exchange rate policies of most countries do not always operate in
sync with their interest rate policies, leading to imbalance and
disequilibrium in their economies. This is because these two related
policies impact different segments of the population differently. Thus
conflicting political dynamics push them in conflicting directions.
Capital generally
prefers a strong currency since it reflects financial
strength, while labor prefers a weak currency to boost exports that
provide domestic employment. Capital prefers high interest rates for
better returns while labor prefers low interest rates for cheaper
consumer loans and affordable mortgages. China will be no exception as
its moves toward interest rate liberalization and free currency
conversion.
Dollar hegemony
enables the US to be the only exception from
macroeconomic penalties of unsynchronized exchange rates and interest
rates. The US, because of dollar hegemony, is the only country that can
claim that a strong currency that leads to trade deficits is in its
national interest in a global economy dominated by international trade.
This is because a strong dollar backed by high interest rates helps
produce a US capital account surplus to finance its trade deficit.
While other
economies must earn dollars to finance their dollar
deficits, US trade and fiscal deficits need only be repaid with dollars
that the US can print at will, not from dollars that the US must earn.
That in essence is the benefit of dollar hegemony to the dollar
economy. But while dollar hegemony is good for the dollar economy, it
imposes costs of job loss and a debt bubble on the US economy.
Off the dollar, and
back
China's exchange
rate policy is not always synchronized with its
interest rate policy. Currency control has protected China from severe
macroeconomic penalties so far. On the exchange rate side, China has
changed the exchange value of the yuan many times since its
introduction on January 1, 1970, when currency reform substituted
10,000 renminpiao for one RMB yuan fixed at an official rate of 2.46
yuan to a dollar. After the collapse in 1971 of the Bretton Woods
regime of fixed exchange rates based on a gold-backed dollar, pressure
grew to appreciate the yuan against a floating dollar no longer backed
by gold. With the RMB's theoretical gold content unaltered, a new
official rate was set on December 23, 1971 at 2.26 yuan to a dollar.
The alarming free fall of the dollar led China to tie the yuan to the
Hong Kong dollar and the British pound sterling.
Hong Kong shifted
from a rule-based currency board to a discretionary
currency board over the course of its monetary history. From 1935 to
1967, Hong Kong as a British colony operated a classic colonial
currency board pegged to the pound sterling, except that private banks
- not the government - issued the currency, a practice that continues
to this day. Instability in the value of the pound in the late 1960s
pushed Hong Kong to switch to a dollar peg. The dollar, too, came under
speculative attack after 1971. To avoid sinking with the dollar, Hong
Kong also decided to let its own currency float. It worked reasonably
well until the commencement of Sino-British negotiations on the return
of Hong Kong to China, which unleashed wild speculation against the
Hong Kong dollar, pushing the free-floating exchange rate temporarily
to 9.6 to 1 on September 24, 1983.
By the end of
October 1983, Hong Kong had ended its brief experiment
with floating exchange rates and announced that it was pegging its
currency to the dollar at a rate of 7.8 to $1 with a discretionary
currency board regime. The peg amounted to an official devaluation from
the pre-crisis floating market rate of 4.6 to 1 to defuse market panic.
In 1985, two years after the adoption of the HK peg, the Plaza Accord,
aiming to halt the rising US trade deficit, pushed the already steadily
falling dollar sharply further down against the yen. The Hong Kong peg
produced a sharply undervalued Hong Kong currency that in turn gave
birth to a bubble economy that burst 12 years later in 1997 as part of
the Asian financial crisis.
The independent yuan
In April 1972, with
the Hong Kong currency free floating, China began
listing an official effective rate for the yuan independent of the Hong
Kong currency. On August 19, 1974, the effective rate of the yuan was
pegged to a trade-weighted basket of 15 currencies, the composition of
which was undisclosed to the market. The effective rate was fixed
almost daily to the floating market value of that basket. By December
31, 1979, the yuan's effective rate rose to 1.5 to a dollar when the US
Federal Reserve under Paul Volcker mounted its heroic struggle to halt
US inflation by raising dollar interest rates to historical heights.
On January 5, 1980,
the State Council issued a decree prohibiting
payments in foreign exchange within China. On April 1, 1980, Foreign
Exchange Certificates (FEC), or waihuijuan, equal in value to
the yuan at the effective rate, were put into circulation, issued to
non-residents in exchange for designated hard currencies, for paying
hotel bills, transportation fares and for purchases at Friendship
Stores. Consumer prices were set at separate levels for the yuan and
the FEC to reflect purchasing power disparity between the two
currencies.
On January 1, 1981,
a foreign trade rate with two categories was
introduced for the RMB. For internal settlements under the foreign
exchange allotment quota, the official rate was set at 2.80 yuan per
dollar. This rate was formed by adding to the effective rate an
"equalization price" for balancing export and import profits and
losses, and applied to all national enterprises and corporations
engaged in foreign trade as well as to receipts and expenditures in
foreign exchange for trade-related transactions in invisibles such as
shipping and insurance.
An experimental
trading system for foreign exchange was established by
the Bank of China in a few areas such as Beijing, Guangdong, Shanghai
and Tianjin. A foreign exchange retention quota also permitted
exporters to retain a portion of export earnings. National enterprises
holding foreign exchange earned through the system of retention quotas
were permitted to sell this foreign exchange to other national
enterprises that had a quota for spending foreign exchange. For
dealings under the foreign exchange retention scheme, the Bank of China
acted as an exclusive broker, charging 0.1%-0.3%, resulting in an
effective rate of 2.803-2.808 yuan per dollar. The effective rate was
applicable to all other transactions, while the official rate was
largely symbolic.
On January 1, 1985,
the internal settlement official rate was abolished
and all trade was governed by the effective rate. On November 20, 1985,
authorization was granted for residents to hold foreign exchange and
open foreign exchange accounts and to deposit and withdraw funds in
foreign exchange. This was to serve residents who might receive foreign
currency funds from relatives and friends overseas, as individuals
generally did not have permission to engage in foreign trade to earn
foreign currency. By the end of November 1985, the yuan, pegged to a
trade-weighted basket of currencies, was trading at 3.2 to a dollar as
a result of the Lourve Accord that pushed the dollar up from the
downward overshoot of the Plaza Accord two years earlier. On January 1,
1986, the trade-weighted basket of currencies peg was abandoned and the
effective rate was placed on a controlled float based on developments
in the balance of payments and in inflation trends and exchange rates
of China's major trading partners and competitors.
In November 1986, a
foreign exchange swap rate was created, based on
rates agreed on between buyers and sellers at over 100 foreign exchange
adjustment centers available to foreign investment corporations and at
first to Chinese enterprises in the four Special Economic Zones of
Shantou, Shenzhen, Xiamen and Zhuhai but expanded in 1988 to all
domestic entities authorized to retain foreign exchange earnings.
Between July 5, 1986 and December 15, 1989, the yuan remained at 3.72
to a dollar, despite the 1987 crash in the US equity markets.
The foreign exchange
swap was set at 5.2 yuan to a dollar on December
31, 1986 and lowered to 5.9 a year later on December 31, 1987, while
the yuan continued to trade at 3.72 to a dollar. Early in 1988, all
domestic entities with retained foreign exchange earnings were granted
permission to trade in the adjustment centers, and by October, 80
adjustment centers were established. Initially, a relatively small
volume of transactions took place in these markets, but the volume
increased substantially after access to the centers was expanded.
On December 31,
1988, the foreign exchange swap rate was again lowered
to 6.60 while the yuan continued to trade at 3.72 to a dollar in the
controlled market at adjustment centers. On February 1, 1989,
regulations were issued governing the use of foreign exchange obtained
in foreign exchange adjustment centers. Imports of inputs for the
agricultural sector, textile and for technologically advance and light
industries were given priority. Purchases of foreign exchange for a
wide range of consumer products were prohibited. On March 1, 1989,
regulations were issued governing domestic sales in foreign currency by
foreign investment corporations. Such corporations were permitted to
sell in China for foreign exchange provided the sales involved
purchases under the government's annual import plan, sales in Special
Economic Zones and other promotional areas, and sales of import
substitutes.
On December 15,
1989, affected by the continuing global impact of the
1987 crash in the US equity markets, the yuan was devalued by 21.2% to
4.72 to a dollar from 3.72. Dollar hegemony was causing the dollar to
rise instead of fall in the face of a massive injection of liquidity by
the Fed in the US money supply to respond to a sudden collapse of US
equity markets that led to a multi-year recession. On December 31,
1989, the foreign exchange swap rate was raised to 5.40 from 6.60,
while the yuan continued to trade at 4.72 to a dollar. On November 17,
1990, the yuan was again devalued by 9.6% to 5.22 to a dollar, with the
foreign exchange swap rate lowered again to 5.70.
On April 9, 1991,
the management of the exchange rate was altered to a
procedure under which the rate would be adjusted frequently as needed
in light of certain indicators of development in international exchange
markets, relative price performance, and trends in export production
costs. On September 11, 1991, new regulations governing the use of
official foreign exchange were introduced. Priority for using foreign
exchange was given to imports of agricultural inputs, interest and
amortization payments and remittances, and imports of key construction
projects and technology. The next priority level included raw materials
used for industrial production, critical spare parts, educational
materials, and medicines. Items for which the use of official foreign
exchange was strictly prohibited included cigarettes, wine, clothes,
shoes, small household appliances, soft drinks, film and other luxury
items.
On October 1, 1991,
specialized banks other than the Bank of China
foreign banks that were engaged in foreign exchange business in
Zhejiang and Jiangsu province began to sell foreign exchange from
export and service receipts directly to local branches of the People's
Bank of China (PBC), later to become the central bank. These banks were
allowed to purchase foreign exchange directly from the PBC to finance
imports. The State Administration for Exchange Control would manage
this part of the exchange reserves under the authorization of the PBC.
After December 1991, individual residents could buy and sell foreign
exchange through authorized banks at rates established in the
adjustment centers in conformity with exchange control regulations.
On December 31,
1991, the foreign exchange swap rate was further
lowered to 5.90 to a dollar. In April 1992, revised guidelines were
issued specifying the priority uses of foreign exchange in adjustment
centers for goods not covered by import licenses. Imports of inputs for
the agricultural sector and central and local construction projects,
and advanced equipment and technology, grain and goods that met daily
needs were given priority. On January 31, 1993, the foreign exchange
swap rate was again lowered to 7.50 while the yuan continued to trade
at 5.75 to a dollar. On July 1, 1993, the exchange rate at which the
state sold 30% of foreign exchange purchased from exporters to certain
enterprises was changed from the effective rate to the prevailing swap
market exchange rate. On December 31, 1993, the foreign exchange swap
rate was lowered to 8.70 while the yuan traded at 5.8 to a dollar.
One and only
On January 1, 1994,
the effective exchange rate and the swap market
rate were unified at the prevailing swap market rate. The PBC would
announce a reference rate for the yuan against the US dollar, the Hong
Kong dollar, and the Japanese yen based on the weighted average price
of foreign exchange transactions during the previous day's trading.
Daily movement of the exchange rate of the yuan against the dollar was
limited to 0.3% on either side of the reference rate as announced by
the PBC.
The buying and
selling rates of the yuan against the Hong Kong dollar
and the Japanese yen might not deviate more than 1% on either side of
the reference rate; and in the case of other currencies, the deviations
should not exceed 0.5% on either side of their respective reference
rates. Issue of export retention quotas ceased except for outstanding
long-term contracts. In addition, Foreign Exchange Certificates (FEC)
ceased to be issued and those in circulation would be withdrawn
gradually.
On April 1, 1994,
the China Foreign Exchange Trade System (CFETS) in
Shanghai (an integrated electronic system for inter-bank foreign
exchange trading) came into operation. Twenty-two cities were linked to
this system by the end of 1994. On July 1, 1996, foreign-funded banks
were allowed to sell foreign exchange for bona fide transactions and
become designated foreign exchange banks. On April 1, 1997, 12 branches
of the PBC began to operate forward purchases and sales of RMB against
underlying transactions on a trial basis. Two years later, on April 1,
1999, the longest maturity of forward purchase and sale of foreign
exchange was extended to six from four months.
Thus on the exchange
rate side, Chinese policy has always been reactive
to US policy. From a high of 1.5 yuan to a dollar in 1979, the yuan,
falling steadily against the dollar, has been fixed at 8.28 to a dollar
since 1995 and remained unchanged through the 1997 Asian financial
crisis, the 1998 and 2000 US recessions when pressure to further
devalue the yuan was resisted by China. Recent US official policy of a
strong dollar being in America's national interest provided the
rationale for holding the yuan-dollar peg.
On the interest rate
side, Chinese policy tended to respond to the
needs of its banking system more than the needs of the Chinese economy.
Between 1979 and 2000, the PBC adjusted loan rates on 19 occasions and
bank deposit rates on 21. China last raised the yuan lending rate on
July 1, 1995 to 12.06% from 10.98 when the yuan exchange rate was
pegged at 8.28 to a dollar. This was at a time when the US Federal
Reserve raised the Fed funds rate (ffr) to 6%, and cross-border flow of
funds between the US and China was strictly controlled. The ffr is the
rate at which US banks loan excess reserves to each other. While the
Fed cannot directly influence this rate, it effectively sets targets
for it through the way it buys and sells Treasuries to banks.
In China, eight
reductions over a period of eight years since 1994
halved the benchmark yuan one-year lending rate to 5.31%. The yuan
one-year deposit rate is now 1.98%. China's consumer price index rose
5.3% in the year through July, meaning that borrowers now enjoy near
interest-free loans after adjusting for inflation. Industrial prices
climbed 14% in the first seven months of 2004, making real interest
rates negative by a wide margin in industrial sectors. Yuan bank
deposits at 1.98% now suffer erosion of principal to inflation at the
rate of 3.32% a year, which then as bank loans goes to support a
built-in 8.69% annual profit for those who borrow at 5.31% to speculate
in the industrial sectors with 14% inflation.
Clash of interests
International money
flow is closely linked to interest rate
differentials between economies, in the direction of the higher rate.
Speculative hot money poured into China for the past two years as the
Fed cut ffr to 1%. Ample liquidity triggered an investment boom in
China that exacerbated inflation. The resulting negative real interest
rate amplified investment demand and caused a speculative bubble. Some
$200 billion has been misallocated to overheated export-related sectors
by the market, with fixed investment running 20% above annual
absorption rate, while non-export-related sectors faced acute capital
shortages.
With a yuan-dollar
peg, keeping yuan interest rates in tandem with
dollar interest rates has been suggested as the only way for China to
stop a further inflow of hot money. China's foreign exchange reserves
rose by $67.3 billion in the first half of 2004 despite a $20 billion
trade deficit that cuts the $30.3 billion in foreign direct investment
to a net of only $10.3 billion. The discrepancy of $57 billion in new
foreign exchange reserves growth is attributable to hot money inflows
sneaking into China in the first six months of 2004, only to be
transmitted through China's central bank into its foreign reserves in
the form of US treasuries.
This requires the
PBC to release 472 billion yuan into China's money
supply. While the Fed raises rates on signs of recovery in the US
economy, China is being pressured to follow the Fed's interest rate
moves even when its domestic economy is slowing because of cost-pushed
inflation, mostly through higher prices for imported fuel and
commodities that are needed by the overheated export sector that
overshoot market growth. While conventional wisdom proclaims that
keeping money too inexpensive for too long is a recipe for trouble for
an unregulated market economy, it is not necessarily so for a planned
economy where credit allocation can be directed by government policy,
or an economy with a currency control regime.
Yet Chinese interest
rates have been well above US and Hong Kong rates
since the Federal Reserve began cutting ffr target 13 times from 6.5%
in January 2001 to 1% on June 25, 2003 and kept it there for a whole
year until June 30, 2004. The Fed lowered the discount rate to 0.75% on
November 6, 2002 and raised it in three steps to 2.75% for primary
(generally sound) financial institutions and 3.25% for secondary (less
creditworthy) institutions. Institutions use the discount window as a
backup rather than a regular source of funding. This meant that banks
could borrow at the discount window at a rate generally 500 basis
points below the ffr until January 9, 2003 when the discount rate was
set at 100 basis points above the ffr. This was another indication that
the Fed was tightening credit while still injecting liquidity into the
US banking system beginning January 9, 2003. The spread between the
discount rate and the ffr continues to be 100 basis points for primary
institutions and 150 basis points for secondary institutions.
Before dollar's
short-term rate began to rise in July 2004 from its
historical low of 1%, as the Fed boosted the short-term rate target for
a third time this year to 1.75% on September 21, the one-year domestic
yuan deposit rate at 1.98% was 142 basis points higher than the 0.56%
one-year domestic dollar deposit rate and 92 basis points higher than
the 1.06% one-year US CD (certificates of deposit) rate. As a result,
dollar funds in the form of hot money seeking quick short-term
speculative profits have been pouring into China, making it difficult
for the PBC to manage rising yuan liquidity levels from the
transmission of these dollar funds into burgeoning foreign exchange
reserves.
As China's foreign
exchange reserves increase, it faces pressure from
the US, Japan, the EU and other trading partners to revalue the yuan
upward. Yet China has begun to incur an overall global trade deficit
that may reach $40 billion in 2004, albeit a sizable and growing
surplus ($124 billion in 2003) continues from its trade with the US.
Domestically, China is reluctant to raise yuan interest rates for fear
of triggering massive loan defaults by distressed borrowers, leading to
a crisis in the already fragile banking system, hoping instead that
import-pushed inflation can be moderated from regulatory measures.
With both exchange
rate policy and interest rate policy kept intact,
China hopes to deal with its overheated economy with administrative
means. To curb rising inflation and runaway speculative investments
fueled by negative interest rates coupled with a fixed exchange rate,
the government since last spring has been trying to rein in China's
overheated economy by canceling projects that had started without
proper regulatory approvals. Administrative measures, such as
restrictions on bank loans for overheated sectors, have slowed the
economy slightly in the past few months. Industrial output moderated
to15.5% in July compared with a year earlier, down from a peak growth
rate of 23% in February.
Time for change?
In theory, price
bubbles and overheated economies are created by the
interaction of interest rates, inflation, exchange rates and credit
allocation policies. Exchange rate theory mandates that if two
economies are linked by freely convertible currencies with floating
exchange rates, free trade and free money flow, the one with higher
inflation and higher interest rates will see the exchange rate of its
currency fall. China now has higher inflation and interest rates than
the US, thus the yuan should fall instead of rise against the dollar
until the inflation rates and interest rates of both economies
equalize, if the yuan were freely convertible at floating rates.
But a weaker yuan
will increase the cost of imports to China thus
adding further to inflation, making the yuan even weaker. A weaker yuan
will also increase exports from China and reduce the supply of goods
and assets in the Chinese domestic market while increasing the supply
of yuan from converting dollar earnings of exporters, thus pushing up
domestic prices, adding to inflation. High inflation will push up
interest rates. But a rise in interest rates increases the financing
cost of production, adding to inflation. High interest rates will also
attract more fund inflows, thus causing more inflation. The net
inflation/deflation outcome from interest rate moves then depends,
among other things, on trade balance. This rationale was given by the
European Central Bank as the logic of refusing to cut euro interest
rates to get the EU economies out of recession. Keeping euro interest
rates stable was needed to fight import-pushed inflation to lift the
euro from trading below par.
There may be a case
for higher prices for Chinese exports in order to
correct the US-China trade imbalance, if the price increase is passed
directly onto higher Chinese wages to increase domestic demand. Chinese
factory wages now range from $60 a month in less developed inland
regions to $160 a month in the more developed coastal regions for an
almost inexhaustible labor force culturally infused with enviable
Confucian work ethics. Chinese wages can double every year for a decade
with positive effects on its economy. Wage-pushed inflation is
beneficial to overcapacity and can defuse an overheated economy by
increasing domestic demand.
The logic of
revaluing the yuan, or any currency, as a means of
balancing trade is flawed. It was ironic that US treasury secretary
Lawrence Summers in the 1990s repeatedly lectured Japan not to
substitute sound macro-economic policy with an exchange rate policy
because the US did exactly that with the Plaza Accord in 1985 and with
its strong dollar policy after the 1997 Asian financial crisis. Robert
Mundell, 1999 Nobel laureate in economics, observed while attending a
conference in Beijing this year that never before in history has there
been a case where international monetary authorities tried to pressure
a country with an inconvertible currency to appreciate its currency. He
said China should not appreciate or devalue the yuan in the foreseeable
future. "Appreciation or floating of the renminbi [RMB] would involve a
major change in China's international monetary policy and have
important consequences for growth and stability in China and the
stability of Asia," Mundell said.
The exchange value
of the yuan is not crucial to the monetary problems
facing the world economy and financial architecture today. Dollar
hegemony, a peculiar phenomenon in which a fiat dollar assumes the
status as the world's main reserve currency is the main
dysfunctionality in the current debt economy and international finance
structure. China is not the problem; dollar hegemony is. China's
economy, despite spectacularly rapid growth, still accounts for only an
insignificant 3.5% of the global GDP, a pathetic figure for a nation
with one fifth of the world's population. Its share of world trade has
risen from less than 1% to 5% in two decades. Most Chinese export
products are sold with a retail price of less than $100 per item. Thus
self-satisfaction of alleged economic miracle is grossly premature.
After two-and-a-half
decades of reform, China is still unable to
accomplish in economic reconstruction what Nazi Germany managed in four
years after coming to power, ie full employment with a vibrant economy
that would challenge that of Great Britain, the then superpower. Post
World War I Germany started with an economy in every way as devastated
as China's, with no prospect of foreign credit, huge war debts and
reparations and a defeatist social milieu. While Nazi philosophy is
detestable, the effectiveness of the national socialist economic
programs of the Third Reich cannot be summarily dismissed.
Yet China now
accounts for 60% of the growth in world trade. This
testifies not to China's strength in trade, but the weakness of world
trade growth, which has been driven not by prosperity, but by falling
wages in the past two decades. Even the rise in foreign direct
investment (FDI) inflows to China is not caused by an undervalued
currency, but rather by the potential of China's domestic market and
growth fundamentals. Yet this potential is constrained by dollar
hegemony, which forces FDI into China's saturated export sector. But
this export sector cannot grow because it is built on the outsourcing
of jobs from the target markets. Rising unemployment in these markets
will shrink demand for Chinese exports.
Wrong target
China's trade
surplus with the US, a key target in the knee-jerk
criticism of China's yuan policy, has actually little direct link with
the exchange rate of the yuan. This trade surplus has been nurtured by
dollar hegemony by design in order to finance the US capital account
surplus. China's recent export performance is primarily driven by the
country's two-decade trade reforms, its abundance of low-wage labor
that has remained low-wage after two-and-a-half decades. And more
importantly, China's growth has been largely led by growing processing
and assembly operations in China for re-export, operated by
transnational corporations mainly to demolish the hard-won gains of
labor movements in the capitalistic West.
Chinese exports have
consistently outperformed the competition at
wide-ranging values of the yuan pegged at different levels to a
fluctuating dollar. The Chinese export boom persisted even during the
turbulent years following the 1997 Asian financial crisis, when strong
market pressure for the yuan to be devalued was resisted. The reason
for this is that Chinese wages are more flexible on the falling side
than on the rising side, as a result of the smashing of the iron rice
bowl by market reform and a labor movement that had not kept pace with
the introduction of socialist market economy.
Exchange rate
movements affect the price of both imports and exports,
but their impact on trade balance may only lead to changes in the
volume of goods and services rather the monetary value of trade. With a
stronger yuan, fewer Chinese goods may be exported to the US at a
higher price; and more US goods and services may be exported to China
at a lower price, but the trade imbalance in monetary value may remain
the same after initial price adjustments. Historical data suggest that
Chinese firms will be required by existing agreements to continue to
compensate foreign investors at previously negotiated rates of return
by lowering Chinese wages. The lower wages will result in lower
domestic demand in the Chinese economy and eventually in the global
economy. And US firms will take advantage of the exchange rate change
to raise prices of US exports. The result may merely be higher
inflation for the US and eventually for the global economy.
As dollar interest
rates rise, China can choose to insulate the impact
on yuan interest rates by re-pegging the yuan upward, or to keep the
current peg by following dollar interest rates trends. But it cannot do
both at the same time without destabilizing China's financial system
and economy. Since the dollar is freely convertible at market rates,
the dollar-pegged yuan is in effect subject to market rate fluctuation
along with the dollar with regard to other currencies. Thus the
stability argument of the dollar peg is deceptive. Fixed exchange rates
seldom produce monetary stability; it only reflects official denial of
economic reality, often at an economy's long-term peril. There are
monetary policy autonomy benefits from controlled convertibility for
any currency, such as insulation from dollar hegemony, but exchange
rate stability is not among them. Policy-induced exchange rates require
central bank intervention that will surface as costs in different forms
in the economy.
In theory, rising
interest rates push up exchange rates. However, this
convention is only operative if rising interest rates reduce inflation.
Rising interest rates can add to inflation under some conditions,
pushing down exchange rates. When dollar interest rates rise, the
dollar gets stronger. But despite recent corrections, the exchange
value of the dollar is still at an 18-year trade-weighted high,
notwithstanding record US current-account and fiscal deficits and the
status of the US as the world's leading debtor nation. There is
persistent talk among trade economists of the need for the dollar to
fall another 20%.
The US inflation
rate has been moderated by low-price imports from
China. Policy-induced upward valuation of the yuan against a rising
dollar will accelerate US inflation. It will drive up US interest rates
at a faster pace, conflicting with the Fed strategy of a "measured
pace" for interest rate moves to avoid scuttling the anemic recovery.
Similarly, raising yuan interest rates may put upward pressure on the
exchange rate of the yuan to the dollar, making Chinese exports more
expensive in dollar terms, creating upward pressure on US inflation
rates and interest rates. These pressures can be resisted, but not
without costs to the US economy.
Thus, recent calls
from US officials for China to simultaneously raise
both the yuan exchange rate to the dollar, and yuan interest rates
further above dollar interest rates are ill advised. Such moves will
cause an upward spiral of interest rates and inflation in the US,
China, Asia and the rest of the world. Yuan interest rates are already
substantially above dollar rates, an upward valuation of the yuan
against the dollar with a rise in yuan interest rates will exacerbate
the destabilizing flow of hot money into China. To understand China's
dilemma on interest rate policy as a key tool in its macro approach to
cooling its overheated economy, one needs to understand the
interlocking relationships of interest rates, inflation, exchange rates
and credit allocation.
Not again
The linkage between
domestic interest rates and the exchange value of a
currency is very direct, with inevitable impacts on foreign trade. An
illustration of this is provided by the Plaza Accord of 1985. After the
US Federal Reserve under Paul Volcker raised federal funds rate (ffr)
on July 8, 1981 to a historical high of 19.93% to fight an annual
inflation rate of over 15% that was still rising, the exchange value of
the dollar rose to cause an alarming US trade deficit, reaching 3.5% of
GDP. The Plaza Accord of 1985 was a coordinated effort by the US, Japan
and Germany, the three main trading nations of the world at the time,
to force the US dollar to fall against the yen and the German mark, in
defiance of market fundamentals, with the purpose of reducing the US
trade deficit. After the Plaza Accord, the Federal Reserve moved the
ffr target in a downward trend, and the ffr fell to 5.56% in October 7,
1986.
The linkage between
the exchange rate and interest rates is less direct
but more destabilizing. The Bretton Woods regime fixed the Japanese yen
at 360 and the mark at four to a dollar until 1971. By 1985, the dollar
was buying only 238 yen and 2.95 mark. Yet the US trade deficit
continued unabated. The Plaza Accord of 1985 pushed the dollar down to
145 yen and 1.79 mark. The Fed then reversed its low interest rate
policy in October 1986. The ffr rose to 7.76% on October 15, 1987 and
yields on 10-year government bonds rose from 7% in January to 9.5%, a
rise that precipitated the 1987 crash four days later.
On October 19, 1987,
the Dow Jones Industrial Average (DJIA) dropped
508 points, or 22.6%, in one day on volume of 608 million shares, six
times the normal volume then (current normal daily volume is over 1.4
billion shares, with top volume of 2.8 billion shares on July 24,
2002), and ending 36.7% lower from its closing high of 2,787 less than
two months earlier on August 25. The immediate trigger that burst the
equity bubble was identified by some analysts in hindsight as
legislation passed by the House Ways and Means Committee on October 15,
eliminating the tax deductibility of interest on debt used for
corporate takeovers.
Interest rate
levels, in combination with exchange rate policies, have
both long-term and short-term relationships to the forming and bursting
of financial bubbles. China now appears determined to avoid repeating
past exchange rate and monetary policy errors made by the US that had
induced the 1987, 1994, 1997 and 2000 crashes.
In response to the
1987 crash, the US Federal Reserve under its new
chairman, Alan Greenspan, with merely nine weeks in the powerful post,
flooded the banking system with new reserves by having the Fed Open
Market Committee buy massive quantities of government securities from
the market. Greenspan announced the day after the crash that the Fed
would "serve as liquidity to support the economic and financial
system". He created $12 billion of new bank reserves by having the Fed
buy up government securities. The $12 billion injection of "high-power
money" in one day caused the ffr to fall by three-quarters of a point
and halted the financial panic, though it did not cure the financial
problem, which caused the economy to plunge into a recession that
persisted for five years.
High-power money
injected into the banking system enabled banks to
create more bank money through credit multiplying, by lending
repeatedly the same funds minus the amount of required bank reserves at
each turn. At 10% reserve requirement, $12 billion of new high power
money could theoretically generate up to $120 billion of new bank money
in the form of bank loans, if demand and borrower credit-worthiness
permit, the absence of which would leave the Fed ineffectively pushing
on a credit string. The injection of liquidity from the Fed cemented
the Plaza Accord devaluation of the dollar into permanence without
correcting the US trade deficit.
The 1987 crash was a
stock market bubble burst that led to a subsequent
real property bubble burst that in turn caused the Savings and Loan
(S&L) crisis two years later. The Financial Institutions Reform
Recovery and Enforcement Act (FIRREA) was enacted by the US Congress in
August, 1989, to bail out the thrift industry in the S&L crisis by
creating the Resolution Trust Corporation (RTC) to take over failed
savings banks and dispose of their distressed assets. The Federal
Reserve reacted to the S&L crisis with a further massive injection
of liquidity into the commercial banking system, lowering the ffr from
its high of 10.71% reached on April 19, 1989 to below the 3% inflation
rate, making the real rate near zero until January 31, 1994.
Since there were few
assets worth investing in a down market, most of
the newly created money went into bonds. This resulted in a bond bubble
by 1993, which then burst with a bang in February 1994 when the Fed
started raising rates, going further and faster than market
participants had expected: seven hikes in 12 months, doubling the ffr
target to 6%. As short-term rates caught up with long, the yield curve
flattened out. Liquidity evaporated, punishing "carry traders" who had
borrowed short-term at low rates to invest longer-term in higher-yield
assets, such as long-dated bonds and more adventurous higher-yielding
emerging-market bonds. The rate increases set off a bond-market crash
that bankrupted Wall Street giant Kidder Peabody & Co, California's
Orange County and the Mexican economy, all casualties of wrong interest
rate bets.
By 1994, Greenspan
was already riding on the back of the debt tiger
from which he could not dismount without being devoured by it. The Dow
was below 4,000 in 1994 and rose steadily to a bubble of near 12,000,
while Greenspan raised the ffr target seven times from 3% to 6% between
February 4, 1994 and February 1, 1995, to try to curb "irrational
exuberance". Greenspan kept the ffr target above 5% until October 15,
1998 when he was forced to ease after contagion from the 1997 Asian
financial crisis hit US markets. The rise in ffr in 1994 did not stop
the equity bubble, but it punctured the bond bubble. Despite the Lourve
Accord of 1987 to slow the Plaza-Accord-induced fall of the dollar, the
dollar fell to 94 yen and 1.43 mark by 1995. The low dollar laid the
ground for the Asian finance crisis of 1997 by fueling financial
bubbles in the Asian economies that pegged their currencies to the
dollar.
US inflation rates
have been under-reported by statisticians in the
name of scientific logic. The first significant downward adjustment
occurred in 1996 on the recommendation of the Boskin Commission, which
had concluded that the US inflation rate had been overstated by an
annual 1.1 percentage points. About half of this overstatement has
since been "corrected".
America's hedonic
pleasures
But further, far
more substantial downward adjustments in the price
indices have resulted from the spreading use of "hedonic" pricing
methods, used to translate quality improvements in products into price
declines even if the actual prices are climbing. Automobiles that now
sell for $30,000 used to sell for $10,000, but the inflation rate of
automobiles is registered as declining because cars are technically
more sophisticated. The consumer is supposed to be getting more "car"
per dollar, never mind no one can now buy a $10,000 car. Rents for
apartments are registered as declining even when rent payment rises,
because renters get air-conditioning, marble bathrooms and granite
kitchens and high rise views. Yes, the higher up you are from the
dirty, noisy street, the more housing you allegedly get per dollar, a
real bargain in hedonic price while the square foot price goes through
the roof. Thus prices can rise with no inflation.
The US Bureau of
Labor Statistics (BLS) expanded the use of hedonic
regressions to compare quality differences in prices. Hedonic
regressions attempt to estimate econometrically the value that
households put on quality differences. These methods are used for
measuring quality distinctions in the categories of apparel, rent and
computers and peripheral equipment, and as of January 1999, they have
been used for television prices. Research is under way to extend this
technique to other categories.
As this measuring
technique is being extended to a growing number of
goods, it has become a most important factor in reducing the US
inflation rate, and intrinsically raises nominal GDP growth while the
real GDP may actually decline. Its overall effect on monitoring the
economy is kept secret from the public. The hedonic price adjustments
for computer hardware and software alone went a long way to explain US
growth and productivity miracles of the past decade.
Another device to
lower the measured US inflation rate is the shift to
"chained" price indexing, used since 1996. It changes the weight of
items in a basket of goods on the assumption that people generally tend
to shift their spending to cheaper goods. If the price of apples rises,
people buy more pears, whose lower prices go into the price index
instead. It is reasonable to suspect that US inflation before the 2001
crash had been hovering around 5% on the old basis, the highest in more
than a decade, and virtually twice the rate in Europe. Inherently, this
would have cut real GDP growth by about 1.5 percentage points and kept
interest rate higher. All this suggests two important things: first,
that the reported new paradigm increases in real GDP and productivity
growth have been exaggerated by a statistical illusion; and second,
that real interest rates have been far too low in relation to real
inflation, which also explains the most rampant money and credit
creation that the US has ever seen in recent history.
Hedonic price
indexing, by keeping the official inflation rate
significantly lower than reality, not only played a key role in fueling
the stock market boom, but also magnified the budget surplus during the
Bill Clinton years and now understates the George W Bush deficit. Such
indexing reduces social security payments and welfare benefits across
the board, as well as undercutting inflation-related wage adjustments.
Essentially, lower hedonic prices in computers and electronic gadgets
are paid for by less money for food and housing of the elderly, the
unemployed and the indigent as well as the average worker.
The most troublesome
fact is that the BLS does not keep contemporaneous
calculations of the "old" method for historical consistency, or reveal
the degree of "new" versus "old" distortion. This cover-up opens
government statistics to challenges of reporting honesty. Bill Gross of
PIMCO, the world's largest bond fund, recently wrote: "The CPI
inaccurately calculates Americans' cost of living. Since social
security and pension benefits as well as the level of wage hikes are
predicated upon the specific number and/or the perception of annual
increases, Americans are being in effect conned by their government and
falling behind the inflationary eight ball year after year. After
slamming the concept of the core CPI, the primary culprits I cited were
the government's use of hedonic and substitution adjustments to lower
the CPI by as much as 1% in recent years."
Look who's talking
Greenspan made his
famous "irrational exuberance" speech at the
American Enterprise Institute in Washington DC on December 5, 1996,
when the Dow was at 6,437, more than twice of the pre-crash 1987 high.
Yet the market kept rising and on January 14, 2000, the Dow peaked at a
hyper-irrational level of 11,723. Two months later, after settling down
to hover around 10,000, it experienced its largest one-day point gain
in history - 499.19 - to close at 10,630.60 on March 16, 2000. John
Maynard Keynes, who famously warned that markets can stay irrational
longer than participants can stay liquid, must have been laughing from
heaven.
Greenspan either
failed to link the rise of equity prices to an
undervalued dollar or he deliberately skirted the issue because foreign
exchange value of the dollar was the province of the Treasury, not the
central bank. Either way, there was nothing irrational or exuberant
about the effect of a fall in the exchange value of the dollar on a
rise in US equity prices. It was a causal effect of a finance bubble
fueled by an undervalued currency, especially when price increases can
be viewed as causing no inflation through hedonic regression.
On April 14, 2000,
some 22 trading days after its largest one-day point
gain, the Dow plummeted 617.78 points, closing at 10,305.77 - its
steepest point decline in a single day historically so far. This
volatility came purely from speculative forces operating on a bubble.
The economy did not change in 22 trading days. When the Dow started its
slide downward after peaking at a historical all-time high of 11,723 on
January 14, 2000, the Fed lowered the ffr target from 6.5% on January
3, 2001, but could not halt the decline. After the Dow hit a low of
7,524 on March 11, 2003, the Fed lowered the ffr target to 1% on June
25, 2003 and kept it there until July 2004. Since then, the Dow, having
climbed steadily to peak at 10,737 on February 11, 2004, fell back to
10,121 by August 31, 2004 when the ffr rose to 1.5% and closed at 9,988
on September 27 with the ffr at 1.75%.
The US trade deficit
was 3.5% of GDP at the time of the 1987 crash. It
was 5.4% by the end of the first quarter of 2004 and rose to $166.2
billion for the second quarter of 2004, annualized to $664.8 billion,
or 6.5% of US-projected GDP. With every passing day, more market
watchers are joining the rank of those predicting looming financial
crisis in US markets from excessive debt, particularly external debt.
This danger cannot possibly be defused by China, regardless of what
monetary policy it adopts. The dismal record of US monetary policy that
induced the 1987, 1994, 1997 and 2000 crashes discounts the value of US
advice for Chinese economic and monetary policy.
Too much of a good
thing
By 1994, excess
liquidity had fueled a worldwide equity rally that
found its way into the Asian emerging markets, where it fed an
unprecedented bubble of easy money in the form of undervalued
currencies pegged to a falling US dollar. When the Asian emerging
market rally crashed abruptly on July 2, 1997, starting with the Thai
central bank running out of foreign exchange reserves trying to
maintain its currency peg, followed by the Russian debt crisis in 1998,
all the major central banks of the world reacted yet again by pumping
even more liquidity into the global banking system. Initially, this
flood of hot money inflated another bond bubble, which popped viciously
in 1999. Then, more liquidity boosted equity prices further and
provided the fuel for the enormous high-tech, Internet and telecom
stock bubbles of 1999 and early 2000.
The first three
years of the 21st century saw a worldwide equity market
crash followed by a recession plagued by overcapacity,
over-indebtedness and over-leverage. And the responses of central banks
were always more liquidity through lower short-term interest rates,
which helped pump up the bond bubble in 2003, with the high fixed
yields of outstanding long bonds translating into higher bond prices.
Excess liquidity supported artificial rallies in housing prices,
equities, corporate debt, commodity prices and mushrooming emerging
markets, particularly China. Fools are calling it a US-led recovery.
The Fed was caught
again in its own ideological vice between
contradicting interest rate policies to balance stimulating growth and
preventing inflation. To avoid the boom-and-bust cycle, the Fed
attempted to drive its monetary vehicle in opposite directions at the
same time, simultaneously fighting inflation and stimulating the
economy. Despite the Fed's announcement that it will raise interest
rate to ward off inflation only at a "measured pace", much talk of a
repeat of a 1994 burst of the bond bubble has since been circulating.
Pushing China to raise yuan interest rates now will only heighten the
Fed's difficulty in keeping its "measured pace" of interest rate hikes.
Bond traders know
that a five-year duration bond fund can drop 5% in
value with an interest rate rise of one percentage point. Conversely, a
one percentage point drop in rates would cause the same fund to
increase by 5% in value. For long-term bond funds with effective
durations of at least seven years, a rise in long-term interest rates
of 2 percentage points over the next 12 months would cause at least a
14% drop in value. With yields on long-term Treasury bonds now around
5%, such an increase would translate into a loss of 9% or more for
shareholders - similar to the last time the Fed tightened monetary
policy in 1994.
Many market
participants intuitively concluded that long-term rates,
following the ffr, would also rise, causing prices of outstanding long
bond to decline. Speculators shorted Treasury long bonds - that is,
they borrowed bonds to sell by promising to return them at a later date
when they hope to buy back the same bonds at a lower price, profiting
from the anticipated price differential. But long-term rates moved
counter-intuitively in the credit markets. What the short-sellers
failed to take into account was that foreign central banks now must buy
each day between $1-2 billion of government bonds to park the
additional foreign exchange reserves they earn from the US trade
deficit. This was a factor of much smaller scale and consequence in
1994 when the bond market collapsed from the Fed raising the ffr target
in quick succession.
Because traders
grossly misjudged the bond market's likelihood to rally
in the face of the Fed tightening and stubbornly hanged onto
conventional intuitive moves in expectation of an easy killing,
throwing in the towel only when it was too late, the rush to cover
short positions pushed bond prices even higher from technical effects
of a short squeeze. On Wednesday, September 22, the 10-year-note fell
below the psychological 4% (3.98%) for the first time since April when
the Fed made its third tightening in 2004. That shifted market
sentiment, and traders decided to stop throwing good money after bad
just to humor Greenspan's fantasy of a recovery. They reacted to the
rise in bond prices as a signal to buy more. It was the market's vote
that the economy would not be heading north for a while.
Shorting on bonds
began when the non-farm payroll unexpectedly surged
by 308,000 in March 2004, suggesting that an end might be in sight for
the three-year-long recession and the corresponding bull run on bonds.
In June, the 10-year note yielded 4.9%, only a few weeks before the Fed
raised the ffr target for the first time in four years. Surely, bond
prices had no place to go but down with a rising ffr, so figured the
smart money intuitively. The market, however, moved counter-intuitively
against the smart money. Morgan Stanley announced on Wednesday,
September 22, that its fixed income trading revenue fell 35% in the
quarter ended August 31 from the previous quarter due mostly to betting
wrong on bond prices falling and rates rising. Most of the other big
firms suffered similar fates. The October 6 Wall Street Journal
reported on dismal second half 2004 bonus outlooks for Wall Street
bankers and traders.
At the current
inflation rate of 1.5%, the neutral rate for ffr is
3.5%, double the current 1.75% target. According to Greenspan's
announced strategy of the "measured pace" of short-term interest rate
rises, it may take a long time to raise seven steps of 25 basis points
each to reach the level of neutrality, if ever, because below-neutral
rates cause more inflation. The Fed may be pedaling hard to reach a
moving target mounted on the front of his interest rate bike. The
harder he pedals, the faster the target moves with him. But the longer
the Fed takes to bring ffr back to neutral or restraining levels, the
bloodier will be the crash of the bond market when it happens. And it
will happen. Reality does not stop merely because some short-sellers
lost money. Borrowing short-term to finance long-term bets is a deadly
game that cannot be made safe by hedging, no matter how sophisticated
the strategy. Hedging does not eliminate risk; it only transmits unit
risk onto systemic risk.
Once the genie of
excess liquidity is out of the bottle, it is almost
inevitable that more genies will get out of more and bigger bottles to
keep the ongoing bubble from bursting to avoid nasty consequences for
the financial system and the real economy. In a planned economy,
liquidity provided by a national bank can serve a constructive purpose
by financing planned growth. In a market economy, liquidity provided by
the central bank lets the market allocate credit to the highest bidders
rather than to where it is needed most in the economy. This means the
liquidity often ends up fueling high-profit speculative bubbles.
Central banks, led
by chief wizard Greenspan, despite their central
role in helping to create financial bubbles, nevertheless declare that
bubbles cannot be anticipated and nothing can be done to prevent them.
But central bankers comfort markets by claiming near-magical power to
handle the destructive consequences of bubbles, through a one-note
monetary policy of rate cuts to inject more liquidity, to save a
bursting bubble by creating a bigger bubble. Greenspan asserted in his
Jackson Hole symposium speech on August 30, 2002 that it is virtually
impossible to diagnose a bubble with any certainty until it bursts, and
even if a bubble could be diagnosed, it is not the task of central
banks to target asset price, but only to control inflation and target
growth. And even if central banks were to react to asset bubbles by
raising interest rates, the extent of the rate hikes needed to reverse
asset prices in times of exuberance might be so large that it would
destabilize the real economy worse than a bubble bursting in its own
course would. Greenspan has admitted more than once that one of the
roles of a central bank is to support the market value of financial
assets.
China's reluctance
to raise yuan interest rates reflects its adherence
to the Greenspan argument that the rate hike needed to slow the
overheated economy is so large that serious economic damage may result,
making the cure worse than the disease, particularly when China's
overheated economy does not manifest itself in a typical stock market
bubble, since its stock market is not fully developed. Chinese stock
market performance is more reflective of anticipatory reactions to
policy reform momentum than actual economic conditions.
China's price bubble
is more like a mountain of foam of tiny bubbles,
each with its own unique characteristics. The steel bubble is caused
not by lack of demand but by bottlenecks of supply, particularly in
electricity and transportation. On the other hand, the real estate
bubble is caused by speculative over-investment in a stagnant
purchasing power environment associated with low wages even for the
growing population of middle-income earners. China has an export
bubble, blown up by the US asset bubble. China's overheated inflation
is not wage-pushed, but import-pushed. China is not the source of world
inflation. It is a re-exporter of inflation from the skyrocketing rise
of imported energy and commodity prices and from speculative
profiteering.
China also faces a
problem in duplicate investment. Localities
understandably copy the successful investment strategies of other
localities. That itself should not be a bad thing for the world's
largest disaggregated domestic market. But much duplicate investment in
China has been concentrated in the export sector, where demand is
externally constrained. The result drives otherwise profitable
enterprises into bankruptcy and exacerbates the non-performing loan
problem in the banking system. The problem then is not with the
duplication of investment in China's huge domestic market, but that
such duplication is not directed to expand the disaggregated domestic
market, but concentrated in the relatively slow growth export market.
Keep your dollars
Led by Japan and
China, East Asian central banks have been acting as
lenders of last resort to rising US external indebtedness so that US
consumers can continue to buy Asian exports. In the process, they are
exporting real wealth to the dollar economy while subjecting their own
local currency economies to mounting financial strains and risk of
instability. Asian central banks now hold about $2.2 trillion, or 80%
of the world's official foreign exchange reserves. Dollar-denominated
assets constituted 70% of these reserves in 2003 while the US share of
the world economy was only 30%. Japan's foreign exchange reserves are
now in excess of $825 billion and China's now exceed $480 billion and
growing. Together, they account for more than half of Asia's total
foreign exchange reserves that are trapped in the dollar economy, while
their own economies are forced to beg for foreign capital denominated
in dollars.
The US current
account deficit reached a record 5.7% of GDP in second
quarter of 2004 and a net national saving rate that fell to 0.4% in
early 2003. It has since rebounded to 1.9% in mid-2004. The US now
absorbs 80% of the world's savings not to finance economic growth, but
to finance debt-fueled over-consumption collateralized by an asset
bubble. In 2003, US net capital investment was 60% below 2000 levels.
US net international
indebtedness is expected to reach 28% of its GDP
by the end of 2004. Since 1990, foreign-owned US assets increased from
less than $2.5 trillion to approximately $10 trillion at the end of
2003 - a fourfold increase, and approaching the entire annual GDP. Over
the same period, US ownership of foreign assets has increased from $2.3
trillion to nearly $7.9 trillion, resulting in a negative net
international investment position for the US, amounting to about $2.7
trillion at the end of 2003 when valuing direct investment at market
value. But in a fundamental sense, the entire $17.9 trillion of assets
are in the dollar economy regardless of location or ownership.
How is the US able
to earn a significantly higher return on its assets
abroad than foreigners earn on their assets in the US? Consider
currency, which pays a zero return. At the end of 2003, dollars held
abroad was estimated to be about $320 billion, whereas only a trivial
amount of foreign currency is held in the US. America's currency
circulating abroad is about half the total US currency outstanding.
That means that the US economy only makes up half of the dollar
economy. The reason the US can do this is because of dollar hegemony, a
phenomenon created by the dollar, a fiat currency no longer backed by
specie value such as gold since the collapse of Bretton Woods in 1971,
continuing to assume the status of a major reserve currency for
international trade. Trade is now a game in which the US produces
dollars by fiat, and the rest of the world produce goods and services
fiat dollars can buy.
The dollar economy
is in fact devouring not just non-dollar economies,
but also the US economy. The dollar is like the rebellious computer HAL
9000 in Stanley Kubrick's 1968 film 2001: A Space Odyssey. Hal 9000 was
programmed to believe that "this mission is too important for me to
allow you to jeopardize it", and proceeded to kill everyone who tried
to disconnect it. Dollar hegemony kills all, pushing down wages
everywhere with no exceptions made for nationality. As Pogo used to
say: "The enemy, it is us."
The issue is not
whether Asian central banks will continue to have
confidence in the dollar, but why Asian central banks should see their
mandate as supporting the continuous expansion of the dollar economy at
the expense of their own non-dollar economies. Why should Asian
economies send real wealth in the form of goods to the US for foreign
paper instead of selling their goods in their own economy? Without
dollar hegemony, Asian economies can finance their own economic
development with sovereign credit in their own currencies and not be
addicted to export for fiat dollars. As for Americans, is it a good
deal to exchange your job for lower prices at Wal-Mart?
Next:
Macro measures and bubbles
|