Chinese Currency
PART IV: China Steady on the peg
By
Henry C K Liu
Part III: Futures Imperfect for China
This article
appeared in AToL
on December 1, 2004
Chinese Prime Minister Wen Jiabao has criticized the US for not taking
measures to halt the dollar's slide and made it clear that China would
not revalue the yuan under pressure. "You must consider the impact on
China's economy and society and also the impact on the region and the
world," Wen said in Laos late Sunday on the sidelines of the
Association of Southeast Asian Nations (ASEAN) meet when asked about
pressures to change the yuan's decade-old peg to the dollar. Wen also
signaled that speculation was too rife in the market at the moment to
make such a change.
The announcement was timely as China stands at the crossroads of
economic destiny, the direction of which will determine if it will be
the latest victim of bankrupt neo-liberal ideology or the sole survivor
that manages to develop an effective immunity from the deadly financial
virus of dollar hegemony that regularly assaults all economies. On a
strategic level, China, the most populous nation on Earth, cannot
possibly expect to develop toward world-class living standards by
exporting to a rich minority of the world's population. The poor
economies' excessive dependence on export to the rich economies under
dollar hegemony will perpetuate the maldistribution of wealth on a
global scale and put China permanently on the lower end of that scale.
For a small, rich segment of the world's population to be the engine of
growth for the entire global economy by consuming the products made by
a poor majority is a formula of global financial imperialism. Financial
imperialism is an advanced stage of old-time industrial imperialism.
Nineteenth-century industrial imperialism of the British model at least
produced industrialized products at the core out of raw material from
undeveloped colonies. Twenty-first-century finance imperialism of the
neo-liberal model uses financial manipulation to make industrialized
colonies produce everything in exchange for fiat money in the form of
dollars.
Imperialism,
now and then
In contrast to industrial imperialism under which the imperialist
economy exports value-added manufactured products for gold, with which
to finance more new modern factories at home, the financial imperialist
economy imports value-added products from the colonies and pays for
them with fiat paper. The colonial economies now export real wealth in
the form of value-added products and get paper in return. To make
matters worse, under dollar hegemony, the fiat paper currency, in the
form of dollars, can only be re-invested in the dollar economy, not
non-dollar exporting economies. Exporting for dollars is merely
shipping wealth out of the exporting economy to the dollar economy. The
dollar economy has become the luxurious front office of the global
economy.
Both forms of imperialism sustain favorable trade terms with the
colonies through political coercion. A sustained trade deficit
supported by currency hegemony is the essence of finance imperialism.
Unlike producers in the industrialized core during industrial
imperialism, producers in the colonies under finance imperialism do not
get richer from producing. They are locked into a low-wage sweatshop
production system so that global inflation can be contained to keep an
ever-expanding supply of fiat dollars valuable. Credit is allotted
through a central bank regime not to the entrepreneurs who can keep
wages rising, but to those who can succeed in pushing wages down with
government blessings. The more dollars the Federal Reserve releases,
the lower world wages must fall to prevent global inflation. The more
the dollar economy expands, the smaller the wage-to-price ratio in
dollar terms. Those economies that defy this iron law of low wages
under dollar hegemony are punished with financial crises that drain
their dollar reserves.
Dollar hegemony renders domestic Keynesian demand management
inoperative. It is no longer economically necessary to manage demand by
raising wages even at the financial core, since consumption can be
maintained by lowering prices of products produced at low-wage
peripheries, paid for by the wealth effect of dollar assets buoyed by a
rising tide of fiat dollars that the Fed can release without limits and
with no penalty or reckoning. Thus under dollar hegemony, money takes
on an additional function as a confiscatory tax on wages, apart from
the conventional functions of store of value and medium of exchange.
This confiscatory role of money on wages works across all national
borders, spreading and perpetuating poverty on the working class all
over the entire globe. Neo-liberal economists call it wage arbitrage
natural to finance market fundamentalism. They put forward the argument
that workers are not unjustly exploited by imperialists or capitalists.
The dismal fate of workers under dollar hegemony, in a neo-Ricardian
iron law of wages, is the logical outcome of a Hayackian amoral market
scientism. The law of the financial jungle has become the ideal of the
capitalist civilization.
Thus socialist China can move toward a "socialist market economy"
without any sense of guilt of betraying its socialist revolution, all
in the name of neo-liberal modernization. In the US, displaced workers
blame low-wage workers overseas, rather than dollar hegemony, for the
predictable fate for workers everywhere. Domestic class conflict is
transformed into nationalistic feuds between workers in conflicting
national economies. Dollar hegemony prevents non-dollar economies from
developing their economies with sovereign credit denominated in local
currencies to finance full employment and rising wages. Dollar
hegemony, operating through unregulated foreign exchange markets,
neutralizes the purchase power disparity between economies and makes it
profitable to outsource high-paying jobs from the US.
China's move toward
market economy along neo-liberal lines was originally intended to be a
brief and temporary program to kick-start its economy off the
stagnation caused by decades of hostile US containment and embargo,
made worse by domestic ultra-radical excesses typical of a garrison
state. But the temporary corrective expediency turned into a permanent
revisionist policy that inevitably led to political instability. The
pressure exploded in the Tiananmen incident in 1989, a decade after the
launching of China's "temporary" economic reform. Misled by biased
Western media with an agenda separate from the target, adverse
international reaction on Tiananmen reverberated around the world,
causing intense hostility toward socialist China, particularly from the
Western anti-communist left, whose members denounced the Chinese
government as being repressive of democracy, ignoring the fact that the
real culprit was a policy drift toward market capitalism away from
socialist planning. The historical fact was that Tiananmen began as a
student mass movement to arrest the erosion of socialism in China.
Domestically, the
real tragedy of Tiananmen was not the alleged abortion of latent
bourgeois democracy, as the Western media tried to spin it. It was the
ossification of a brief transitory strategy of market liberalization in
order to build better socialism into a lasting policy of permanently
postponing socialist construction. This policy is rationalized with all
kind of revisionist ideological mumbo-jumbo, such as China must first
go through a long capitalist stage before it can move onto a socialist
stage, and let some people get rich first. The word "first" was then
conveniently drop and the slogan became: let some people get rich,
period. Yet there is solid evidence that China has successfully
leapfrogged into the space age without repeating the costly
experimentation of another century of the sub-orbital aviation. It is
then a puzzle why socialism has to be postponed and wait for its
gradual evolution from a restoration of capitalism.
There is no logic in insisting on repeating the mistakes of the
capitalist West by copying a bankrupt market system bent on recurring
self-destruction. Yet Margaret Thatcher's fanatic TINA (there is no
alternative) mantra is accepted as the gospel of truth. Income
disparity and wealth maldistribution natural to market economies are
celebrated as necessary dynamos of prosperity. Economics, unlike
truth-respecting physics from which it pilfered many theoretical
concepts, tends to hang on to obsolete ideas long proved dysfunctional
by events with ever more sophisticated rationalization. While Issac
Newton is now a relic in the history of physics, Adam Smith is alive
and well in the temples of economic thought more than two centuries
after his time. China, after half a century of socialist revolutionary
struggle, also swallowed the neo-liberal propaganda that only market
capitalism can bring prosperity.
The
Tiananmen tragedy
The tragedy of Tiananmen in 1989 is that it sounded the death knell of
socialist revolution and heralded the restoration of capitalism in
China. Tiananmen began as a backlash grassroots political reaction to
wholesale official rejection of socialist principles and ideology. The
students at the beginning of the Tiananmen incident protested against
the ill effects of the introduction of market fundamentalism in the
Chinese economy. They wanted to preserve full government financial
support for education, particularly generous socialist benefits for
students, and protested against high unemployment, income inequality
and widespread corruption associated with the move toward market
economy.
Such demands at first received sympathetic hearings from the top
leadership. Alas, wholesome student sentiments were quickly manipulated
to turn intransigent by the US media at the scene to cover the state
visit of president Mikhail Gorbachev of the USSR in its final stage of
implosion, taking on the form of counter-revolutionary demands for
political liberalization toward bourgeois democracy. While the students
were actually demanding more government protection from the erosion of
socialist rights and privileges gained for them by their heroic
parents, the Western media distorted the student protests as demands
for free markets and bourgeois democracy. Naive protesters were
selectively featured by the US media on global television to recite
Abraham Lincoln's Gettysburg Address in broken English, never mind that
the speakers obviously had no understanding of US history and politics,
let alone the statist and interventionist context of Lincoln's
inspiring words.
The leadership in the Communist Party of China (CPC) at that historical
moment was divided. While some remained sympathetic to a student
movement to preserve socialism, others found it imperative to
decisively crush a manipulated political revolt against a socialist
government. In a fateful turn of tactics in the aftermath of the
resultant tragic violence, the CPC leadership decided to preserve
political control through further market liberalization, thus
forfeiting its equalitarian socialist mandate in favor of authoritative
institutional economics based on administrative intervention on free
markets. A decade and a half after Tiananmen, the CPC is now forced to
officially acknowledge the problem of the continued ability of the CPC
to govern effectively. The phrase zhi zheng neng li
("governance capability") surfaced in mid-September 2004, when the CPC
Central Committee was reported by The People's Daily as "discussing the
cultivation of the ruling party's governing competence". The
authoritative paper noted that it was the first time during the 55
years of history after the new China was founded that "the country's
ruling elite considered how to improve the party's governance ability
at an annual plenum of the central committee".
It is a conceptual oxymoron for a communist party to govern a market
economy. Yet despite all the ideological, strategic and tactic errors
of the past three decades, the CPC is far from being an irrelevant
political institution as it remains the only political organization
with the determination and ability to preserve the territorial
integrity and independent sovereignty of China. The history of the
Chinese economy shows that most periods of prosperity in four millennia
had operated under the socialist principle of a commonwealth of Great
Harmony (Da-tong) as opposed to the
capitalist principle of petty bourgeoisie (Xiao-kang). The realities of
Chinese society will soon turn the CPC back on its historic socialist
track and wake up its leadership from the fantasy that only market
capitalism can effectively mobilize the masses for national
construction. Market fundamentalism will only lead China to fall again
into its past dismal fate under the Kuomintang, whose socialist path
had been diverted with the assassination on August 20, 1925, of leftist
leader Liao Zhong-kai after the death of Sun Yat-sen, resulting in a
bankrupt economy that provided the socio-economic backdrop for
continuing semi-colonial exploitation by Western powers and the rise of
the CPC as a liberating force for national revival.
But dollar hegemony injures not only the working class. Even the
comprador class of finance imperialism is also periodically stripped of
their ill-gained wealth by recurring financial crises caused by dollar
hegemony. Still the multi-trillion dollar losses from the recurring
financial crises and bubble bursts of past decades circling the globe
did not all come from the rich. Some of it came from the hard work for
low pay of the working poor, funneled to the rich through structural
systemic economic injustice disguised as market forces. But most of it
came from institutional depositories of worker pensions. Young workers
are being forced to pay for the systemic losses of financial crises
through the loss of jobs and reduction of benefits their parents once
enjoyed. Retired workers are also forced to pay for the systemic losses
through drastic shrinkage in the value of their retirement nest eggs.
The enviable workers' benefits won through century-long struggles of
labor organization in the industrialized core have been swept away by
neo-liberalism in the name of competitiveness, while workers in the
emerging economies are deprived of the minimum social progress their
counterparts in the advanced economies already won a century ago.
Under
neo-liberalism, even if and when the Chinese economy should finally
catch up with the US economy, which under dollar hegemony is in theory
equivalent to trying to catch up with one's own shadow in a setting
sun, what Chinese workers have waiting for them at the end of the
market fundamentalism rainbow is not a pot of gold, but the same dismal
fate facing the US workers today, ie, to have their jobs outsourced to
another still-lower-wage economy. China's industrial heartland will
look like the rust belt in the US, where high-pay factory jobs have
disappeared to low-wage economies and once-booming factories sold for
scrap metal.
Race
to the bottom
The result will be a global economy of more severe overcapacity, with
wages too low and jobs too scarce to provide the purchasing power to
buy the products workers produce. There was a time when a government
printed money recklessly and hyperinflation would follow. Now, under
dollar hegemony, when the US Federal Reserve prints dollars, inflation
is kept under control by outsourcing high-wage jobs to low-wage
economies while wealth becomes increasingly concentrated. Neo-liberal
economists fail to understand that money is useless unless broadly
distributed and spent. Neo-liberal monetary policies tend to inject
liquidity only on the supply side as investment, an obviously wrong
target in an overcapacity economy. Overcapacity is a direct outcome of
excess return on capital from regressively low wage schemes. Liquidity
should be injected to support demand management, by providing full
employment with rising wages until overcapacity is eliminated.
Unregulated credit markets inevitably become failed markets by
directing credit where it is least constructive.
In China, the 1995 Central Bank Law granted the People's Bank of China
(PBoC) central bank status, changing it from its historical role of a
national bank in a planned economy. Central banking insulates monetary
policy from national economic policy by prioritizing the preservation
of the value of money over the monetary needs of a sound national
economy. The ideological assumption asserts that a sound currency is
the sine
qua non of
a sound economy. It is an assumption that is neither logically true nor
empirically supported. A global international finance architecture
based on an unregulated currency market with full convertibility at
market rates in the context of universal central banking allows an
increasingly volatile foreign exchange market to facilitate the instant
cross-border ebb and flow of capital and debt. This instant
cross-border flow of funds can be devastatingly destructive with little
advance warning. Central banking thus relies on domestic fiscal
austerity and monetary contraction imposed through high interest rates
to achieve its institutional mandate of maintaining the exchange value
of the local currency and to prevent destabilizing fund outflow.
In contrast, a national bank does not seek independence from the
government policy. National banking views itself as in a supportive
role of national economic policy. Independence of central banks is a
euphemism for a shift from institutional loyalty to economic
nationalism toward institutional loyalty to the smooth functioning of a
globalized international financial architecture. The international
finance architecture at this moment in history is dominated by dollar
hegemony, which can be simply defined as a fiat dollar's unjustified
status as a global reserve currency. National banking then seeks
insulation and independence from the international finance architecture
dominated by dollar hegemony.
The mandate of a national bank is to finance the sustainable
development of the national economy, and its function aims to adjust
the value of a nation's currency to a level best suited for achieving
that purpose within a regime of exchange control. On the other hand,
the mandate of a modern-day central bank is to safeguard the value of a
nation's currency in a globalized financial market of no or minimal
exchange control, by adjusting the national economy to sustain that
narrow objective, through domestic fiscal austerity, economic recession
and negative growth if necessary. International trade under central
banking dominated by dollar hegemony becomes a race toward the bottom
with beggar thy neighbor competition, rather than true comparative
advantage.
In response to dollar hegemony, PBoC has adopted a monetary policy
stance in 2004 designed to rein in excessive money and credit growth,
avoid excessive interest rates volatility and accelerate interest rate
liberalization. Such a policy stance deals with the symptoms but not
the causes of economic trends deemed undesirable by policymakers.
Moreover, these policy objectives are cross-neutralizing on one
another.
The PBoC expects to keep M1 (currency in circulation plus the checkable
deposits in depository institutions) and M2 (M2 includes M1 plus retail
non-transaction time deposits) growth rate at around 17% for 2004,
still a destabilizingly high rate when GDP (gross domestic
product) growth is targeted to be less than 7%. The outstanding
yuan broad money, or M2, including money in circulation and all bank
deposits, surged 19.1% year-on-year to 23.36 trillion yuan ($2.8
trillion) by the end of April 2004, albeit the increase was slightly
less than that of March. This M2 level is extraordinarily high in
relation to Chinese GDP of $1.4 trillion, amounting to 200%. The US M2
was $6.289 trillion in June 2004 against a GDP of $10.7 trillion, about
60%. And the US money supply is considered excessive. Much of China's
large M2 is caused by recent massive foreign exchange transmission of
hot money. At the end of July, M2 was up by 20.7% from the same period
last year, higher than the central bank's planned growth of 17%.
Over the past two
years, China's foreign-exchange reserves have grown rapidly, not from
trade surpluses, but from the inflow of hot money. This has led to a
substantial increase in yuan "base money" injection as a result of
increased foreign exchange transmission. In line with its overall money
and credit plan, the PBoC has attempted to prevent excessive growth of
base money by withdrawing of yuan through open market operation. This
has the effect of siphoning money from the domestic sectors to the
export-related sectors where dollar hot money is concentrated.
Since April 22, the
PBoC has intensified currency withdrawal from circulation through
issuing central bank bills. In 2003, base money injection as a result
of foreign exchange transmission added up to 1.15 trillion yuan, while
open market operation withdrew 269.4 billion yuan base money, resulting
in a net base money injection of 876.5 billion yuan. By the end of
2003, the PBoC had made 63 issues of central bank bills, amounting to
722.68 billion yuan, leaving an outstanding additional currency amount
of 337.68 billion yuan. The money withdrawal came from the domestic
sectors and the injection went mostly to export and export-related
sectors, including speculative real estate markets. The bulk of the
yuan withdrawal went to foreign reserves holdings. This monetary
exercise was essentially borrowing from the yuan economy to finance the
rise in China's foreign reserves, which lent mostly to the dollar
economy in the form of US Treasuries.
The PBoC also aims to keep new bank lending for 2004 around 2.6
trillion yuan. Banks lent 835.1 billion yuan in new loans in the first
quarter, representing 32% of the annual target and an increase of 24.7
billion yuan from a year ago. New loans by commercial banks between
January and July soared to 1.9 trillion yuan, more than the 1.8
trillion yuan that they lent in all of 2002. But as banks are bypassed
in the US by debt securitization in credit markets, Chinese banks are
being bypassed by the age-old tradition of private loan syndication,
which historically have been the financing of choice among overseas
Chinese, when banks around the world routinely discriminated against
immigrant Chinese borrowers and forced them to develop their own ethnic
credit market.
Macro measures have
little effect on this growing informal Chinese domestic credit market,
where interest rates can be higher than sub-prime credit-card rates in
the US. The real problem is the absence of an effective national credit
allocation policy. Central bank interest-rate liberalization works
against a national credit allocation policy and allows the market to do
the allocation. In unregulated credit markets, credit flows to
borrowers willing to pay the highest interest cost, which usually means
the highest-risk speculative ventures, rather than to where the
national economy needs credit most.
The PBoC claims
that the ultimate objective of this monetary policy stance is to
maintain balanced economic growth at a 7% rate target for 2004, holding
consumer price index (CPI) around 3%. With "macroeconomic adjustment
and regulatory measures", the hangover effect is expected to contribute
2.2% to CPI, with new inflation factors and price adjustment policies
contributing 1%. The main monetary policy instruments are open market
operation, bank reserve requirement, interest-rate policy, re-lending
and re-discount, and credit policy.
The PBoC measures
growth by GDP readings, as is common by international standards. Gross
domestic product is a measure of national income. Dollar hegemony
distorts GDP as a reliable index of growth for non-dollar economies
since GDP includes foreign-reserves holdings when in effect such funds
have left the local currency economy. Taking away annual rises in
foreign-reserves holdings, real Chinese GDP is substantially lower than
the $1.4 trillion figure. Take away also foreign-factor income in the
form of returns on foreign capital, and real Chinese GDP may be
half of what the misleading statistics show, since 54% of China's
exports are traded by foreign investors. If one should ask to where has
all the money gone given China's annual GDP growth of 9%, the answer is
that most of it went to the dollar economy.
Moreover, this
policy stance is in essence a neo-liberal supply-side
approach. It is couched in typical policy jargon prevalent among
central bankers, trapped by the flawed logic of the Washington
Consensus and International Monetary Fund (IMF) snake-oil orthodoxy.
The Chinese economy at this stage of its development does not need a
tight monetary policy to fight overheating in some sectors any more
than Chinese agriculture needs a drought to prevent soil-erosion from
spring flood. What China needs is a new focused credit policy to shift
from dependence on dollar-financed and -denominated export, and to
institute full deployment of yuan sovereign credit insulated from
dollar hegemony to finance the rapid development of its undeveloped
domestic economy.
It needs to dampen the overheated export sectors with administrative
means and stop letting an unregulated international financial market
direct national economic policy. China needs to stop exporting real
wealth by reducing export of goods produced by low wages for useless
fiat dollars and refocus on real growth of its domestic economy. China
needs to free its currency from dollar hegemony and to stop letting the
international credit market dictate national development. Wealth
denominated in dollars has very limited use in China. It only forces
the PBoC to inject yuan money supply into China's export sector so that
China can finance US national debt with its dollar trade surplus.
Financial comprador mentality is apparently dominating the policy
establishment in the PBoC, which mistakes the size of its foreign
reserves for national financial strength and confuses the health of the
banking system under its regulatory supervision with the economic
health of the nation. China's banks are basket cases only because China
chooses to shift from a national banking regime to a central banking
regime. Now the central bank wants to sacrifice the national economy to
cure sick private commercial banks under its supervision, whose
sickness ironically has been caused by a central banking regime.
Forex
folly
Under dollar hegemony, an economy that holds or needs to hold large
foreign-exchange reserves in the form of dollars is a financially weak
economy. The need for foreign reserves is clear evidence that the rest
of the world has no confidence in that country's currency and by
extension, its domestic economy. The US, a global financial powerhouse,
holds very little foreign currency. Japan and Germany, as defeated
nations of World War II, have no option other than to be trapped in an
international finance architecture dominated by dollar hegemony. It is
a sign of serious poverty of insight, creativity and independent
thought at the top that China's monetary establishment chooses
voluntarily to play the same handicapped game as these two
once-vanquished nations.
At the same time, the PBoC has provided liquidity to support the
privatization of financial institutions through flexible market
operation. This liquidity is not used to finance national economic
expansion, but to finance initial public offerings (IPOs) of privatized
banks. Banks in a national banking regime are social institutions, but
in a central banking regime, banks are private institutions.
Privatization of social institutions is a dubious neo-liberal
undertaking that requires close government supervision and regulation
to justify. Central-bank-provided liquidity for the purpose of
facilitating the privatization of state-owned banks takes on the form
of legalized theft from the public. It provides public subsidy in the
form of interest-free loans to the favored buyers of the privatized
banks.
At the end of August 2003, the IPO of Huaxia Bank led to substantial
liquidity shortage in commercial banks. Under such a circumstance, the
PBoC, on August 26 and September 2, 2003, twice reduced the issuance
scale of three-month central bank bills and injected liquidity to
commercial banks through seven-day reverse repo transactions. At the
time of the Changjiang Power IPO on November 11, 2003, the PBC again
conducted seven-day reserve repo transactions. Under the guidance of
open market operation, the seven-day repo rate and typical inter-bank
interest rates remained stable at around 2.15% despite liquidity
volatility resulting from IPOs, which indicated that open market
operation reached expected targets. Free money was handed over by the
central bank to favored private borrowers to buy privatized state-owned
assets.
Given sufficient liquidity of financial institutions and falling trend
of money market rates during the first quarter of 2004, the PBoC
intensified sterilization operation, using open market operations to
counteract the effects of exchange market intervention on the country's
monetary base. In this period, the cumulative amount of central bill
issuance reached 435.2 billion yuan and outstanding amount stood at
615.45 billion yuan. Base money injection as a result of foreign
exchange purchase amounted to 291.6 billion yuan, and open market
operation withdrew 281 billion yuan, resulting in a net base money
injection of 10.6 billion yuan and basically offsetting the foreign
exchange position of base money.
With fixed exchange rates, when excess foreign currency seeks to
exchange into the home currency, as in the case of China in the past
two years, the monetary authority must supply additional home
currencies to keep the exchange rate fixed, even with controlled
convertibility. The monetary authority buys up the excess foreign
currency with local currency and increases its foreign exchange
reserves. This operation increases the supply of home currency in
private circulation. When a central bank intervenes to keep a fixed
exchange rate, it needs to sterilize its foreign exchange intervention
by taking separate actions to prevent the home money supply from rising
or falling due to foreign exchange intervention. In the case of
sterilization, the authorities will simultaneously buy or sell foreign
currency and sell or buy interest-bearing domestic debt or assets to
remove the excess or add depleted home currency, offsetting any effect
on the home money supply.
However, if the money supply stays unchanged, then according to the
laws of open interest-rate parity, the monetary authority can keep the
exchange rate fixed only by lowering domestic interest rates. Any
excess supply of foreign currency that existed before will remain. It
disappears only from the domestic money supply, and now reappears in
the form of foreign-exchange reserves. The home interest rate will have
to fall to offset pressure on the exchange rate to rise. Otherwise,
inflow of hot money will continue.
Thus the recent rise of the one-year benchmark interest rate by 27
basis points to 5.58%, effective from October 29, 2004 - the first such
hike in nine years - with the rise of one-year deposit rate to 2.25%
from 1.98%, is a counterproductive move in the context of managing
hot-money inflow. The central bank also moved a step toward the goal of
interest-rate liberalization, scrapping the upper limits on yuan
lending rates. Banks can now charge as much as they want for yuan
loans. The last time the PBoC raised lending rates was in July 1995,
and the rates were last changed in February 2002, when they were
lowered to boost a sluggish economy.
These measures will only attract more inflow of hot dollars that had
been caused by the gap between dollar interest rates and yuan interest
rates to begin with. According to the principle of open interest-rate
parity, if a monetary authority sterilizes, its ability to keep the
exchange rate fixed depends on the market's aversion to exchange risk -
an aversion ironically exacerbated by a fixed exchange rate not
supported by a corresponding interest rate policy. Thus it is
irrational for the PBoC to raise interest rates to cool the economy
while the overheating was created by an inflow in hot foreign money due
to high yuan interest rates. Those who advise the PBoC to raise yuan
interest rates lack adequate understanding of the relationship between
interest rates and foreign-exchange rates and the impact of hot foreign
money on domestic money supply in a fixed exchange-rate regime.
A central bank wanting to hold the exchange rate of its currency fixed
against upward market pressure supplies domestic currency to the
market, creating pressure for the nominal interest rate of the home
currency to fall. This causes bonds prices to rise. A fall in the
nominal interest rate spurs aggregate demand, which causes GDP and the
price level of the economy to rise. This expansion of the economy - in
particular, the rise in consumption and investment - may have been a
completely unintended side effect of the central bank's actions.
A foreign-exchange intervention is said to be unsterilized if its
effects are allowed to pass through to domestic inflation and domestic
GDP, and is said to be sterilized if its effects are not allowed to
pass through. A central bank sterilizes its foreign-exchange
interventions with open-market operation following foreign-exchange
intervention. The central bank's desire to fix the domestic currency
below market pressure leads to an expansion of domestic money supply,
causing nominal interest rates to fall, which then spurs aggregate
demand. If the central bank does not want to affect aggregate demand,
then an open-market operation to maintain the nominal interest rate at
its pre-intervention level is normally required. But there are
alternative regulatory options, such as lifting bank reserve
requirements, if the central bank does not want to change interest
rates, albeit such alternatives are not without economic cost. The PBoC
had elected to employ such alternatives until it succumbed to raising
yuan interest rates in October.
In order to rein in the obviously excessive credit growth, the PBoC had
raised the required reserve ratio by 1% to 7% on September 21, 2003.
The central bank raised the reserve requirement for commercial banks by
half a percentage point to 7.5% effective April 25, 2004, and has
called for banks, enterprises and local governments to help curb
investments and cool down the economy. The new requirement applies to
the country's big four state-owned banks, 11 joint-stock banks and more
than 100 urban and rural commercial banks. However, thousands of rural
and urban credit cooperatives will maintain the existing 6% reserve
requirement.
Bank reserves are a percentage of total deposits that commercial banks
must maintain for risk management. Only deposits over the minimum set
by the central bank may be used for lending. The higher reserve will
freeze approximately an additional 110 billion yuan (US$13.3 billion)
in commercial banks' liquidity. The 0.5-percentage-point reserve hike
is largely to prevent runaway growth of money and credit and keep the
national economy expanding on a steady, fast and healthy track.
Excessive credit growth could cause inflation, asset price bubbles, new
non-performing loans at commercial banks and systemic financial risks.
Financial institutions' reserves at the central bank now exceed 2
trillion yuan. The China Banking Regulatory Commission (CBRC) has
ordered banks to stop lending to steel, aluminum, cement, real estate
and automobile industries.
Calling
on the reserve
Conventional money and banking theories regard required reserve ratio
hiked as a relatively drastic measure compared with changes in
interest rates. Nevertheless, the PBoC interpreted it as a mild and
preferred move. The reason is that the PBoC has to withdraw a large
amount of excess liquidity because of fast growth of foreign-exchange
reserves. To do so, if the central bank only issues CB bills without
any other measure, it has to raise the interest rates on CB bills to a
very high level given strong expansion momentum in the export sector
and the commercial banks' wide interest-rate differentials over the
returns on CB bills. However, a high interest rate would have
significant adverse implications on the whole economy. Moreover, it
would exacerbate the inflow of hot foreign money. In contrast, the 1.5%
rise of required reserve ratio enabled the central bank to reduce at a
lower economic cost the commercial banks' excess reserve by about 260
billion yuan, accounting for only 9% of their holdings of Treasury
bills, financial bonds and CB bills.
Therefore, the new required reserve ratio hike was considered a
comparatively mild policy measure. The operative word is
"comparatively", for the measure was far from mild. Still, the policy
was announced one month in advance, giving time for financial
institutions to manage their liquidity. The PBoC also provided timely
support to those financial institutions with short-term liquidity
difficulties so as to maintain the overall stable development of
financial operation and money market interest rates. Still, with each
additional percentage point of reserve requirement tying down 260
billion yuan in excess reserves, a 7.5% reserve ratio translates into a
reduction of more than 1 trillion yuan of bank loans, which may help
achieve the new lending target for 2004 to around 2.6 trillion yuan,
but it would not provide much help to the economy, particularly the
depressed sectors. Since the overheating is concentrated mostly in
export and export-related sectors of the economy, there is no
compelling logic to reduce aggregate demand for the whole economy with
a nationwide bank reserve ratio.
But a larger question about the monetary effectiveness of bank reserve
requirements needs to be addressed. Reserve requirements, a tool of
monetary policy, are computed as percentages of deposits that banks
must hold as vault cash or on deposit at a central bank. Reserve
requirements represent a cost to the banking system. Bank reserves are
used in the day-to-day implementation of monetary policy by the central
bank.
As of June, the reserve requirement for US banks was 10% on transaction
deposits (checking and other accounts from which transfers can be made
to third parties), and there were zero reserves required for time
deposits. The US Monetary Control Act (MCA) of 1980 authorizes the
Fed's Board of Governors to impose a reserve requirement of from 8% to
14% on transaction deposits and of up to 9% on non-personal time
deposits (those not held by an individual or sole proprietorship). The
Fed may also impose a reserve requirement of any size on the amount
depository institutions in the US owe, on a net basis, to their foreign
affiliates or to other foreign banks. Under the MCA, the Fed may not
impose reserve requirements against personal time deposits except in
extraordinary circumstances, after consultation with Congress, and by
the affirmative vote of at least five of the seven members of the Board
of Governors.
In order to lighten the reserve requirements on small banks, the MCA
provided that the requirement in 1980 would be only 3% for the first
$25 million of a bank's transaction accounts, and that the figure would
be adjusted annually by a factor equal to 80% of the percentage change
in total transaction accounts in the US. An adjustment late in 2003 put
the amount at $45.4 million. Similarly, the Garn-St Germain Act of 1982
provided for a 0% reserve requirement for the first $2 million of a
bank's deposits. This level, too, rises each year as deposits grow, but
it is not adjusted for declines in deposits. For 2004, that level is
$6.6 million. The transactions-account reserve requirement is applied
to deposits over a two-week period: a bank's average reserves over the
period ending every other Wednesday must equal the required percentage
of its average deposits in the two-week period ending the Monday
sixteen days earlier. Banks receive credit in one two-week period for
small amounts of excess reserves they hold in the previous period.
Similarly, a small deficiency in one period may be made up with excess
reserves in the following period. Banks that fail to meet their reserve
requirements can be subject to financial penalties.
Reserve requirements affect the potential of the banking system to
create transaction deposits. If the reserve requirement is 10%, for
example, a bank that receives a $100 deposit may lend out $90 of that
deposit. If the borrower then writes a check to someone who deposits
the $90, the bank receiving that deposit can lend out $81. As the
process continues, the banking system can expand the initial deposit of
$100 into a maximum of $1,000 of money. In contrast, with a 20% reserve
requirement, the banking system would be able to expand the initial
$100 deposit into a maximum of $500. Thus, higher reserve requirements
should result in reduced money creation by banks and, in turn, in
reduced economic activity.
In practice, the connection between reserve requirements and money
creation is not nearly as strong as the exercise above would suggest.
Reserve requirements apply only to transaction accounts, which are
components of M1, a narrowly defined measure of money. Deposits that
are components of M2 and M3 (but not M1), such as savings accounts and
time deposits, have no reserve requirements and therefore can expand
without regard to reserve levels. Furthermore, the Federal Reserve
operates in a way that permits banks to acquire the reserves they need
to meet their requirements from the money market so long as they are
willing to pay the prevailing price (the federal funds rate) for
borrowed reserves. Consequently, reserve requirements currently play a
relatively limited role in money creation in the US.
Reserve requirements, the discount rate (the interest rate that Federal
Reserve Banks charge depository institutions for short-term loans), and
open market operations (buying and selling of government securities)
are the Fed's three main tools of monetary policy. There is a continual
flow of reserves among banks, representing the ever-changing supply and
demand for these reserves at individual banks. When the Fed engages in
open market operations, it adds to or subtracts from the supply of
reserves. The effectiveness of the Fed's actions results from the
reasonably predictable demand for reserves that is created by reserve
requirements.
The Fed changes reserve requirements for monetary policy purposes only
infrequently. Reserve requirements impose a cost on the banks equal to
the foregone interest on the amount by which required reserves exceed
the reserves that banks would voluntarily hold in order to conduct
their business, and the Fed has been hesitant to make changes that
would increase that cost. There have been only a handful of
policy-related reserve requirement changes since the MCA was passed in
1980. In March 1983, the Fed eliminated the reserve requirement on
non-personal time deposits with maturities of 30 months or more, and in
September 1983, it reduced that minimum maturity to 18 months. Then, in
December 1990, the Fed cut the requirement on non-personal time
deposits and on net Eurocurrency liabilities from 3% to 0%. In April
1992, it cut the requirement on transaction deposits from 12% to 10%.
In announcing its December 1990 move, the Fed noted that the cut would
reduce banks' costs, "providing added incentive to lend to creditworthy
borrowers". Similarly, in announcing its April 1992 cut in reserve
requirements, the Fed observed that the reduction would put banks "in a
better position to extend credit".
Current reserve requirements are low by historical standards. From 1937
to 1958, the rate on demand deposits was always at least 20% for banks
in New York and Chicago, which were "central reserve cities" - a term
now obsolete. Before the passage of the MCA in 1980, only banks that
were members of the Federal Reserve System had to meet the Fed's
reserve requirements. State-chartered banks that were not Federal
Reserve members had to meet their state's reserve requirements, which
typically were lower. As a result, many banks dropped their Federal
Reserve membership and member bank transaction deposits fell from
nearly 85% of total US transaction deposits in the late 1950s to 65%
two decades later, weakening the Fed's ability to influence the money
supply.
The MCA sought to solve this problem by authorizing the Fed to set
reserve requirements for all depository institutions, regardless of Fed
membership status. The Fed has long advocated the payment of interest
on the reserves that banks maintain at Federal Reserve Banks. Such a
step would have to be approved by Congress, which traditionally has
been opposed to this because of the revenue loss that would result to
the US Treasury. Each year the Treasury receives the Fed's revenue that
is in excess of its expenses. The payment of interest on reserves would
be an additional expense to the Fed.
Capital
adequacy
Apart from bank reserve requirement that is designed to insure
liquidity, a private bank's capital - also known as equity - is the
margin by which creditors are covered if the bank's assets were
liquidated. A measure of a bank's financial health is its capital/asset
ratio, which is required to be above a prescribed minimum international
standard set by the Bank of International Settlement (BIS), whose rules
set requirements on two categories of capital, Tier 1 capital and Total
capital. Tier 1 capital is the book value of its stock plus retained
earnings. Tier 2 capital is loan-loss reserves plus subordinated debt.
Total capital is the sum of Tier 1 and Tier 2 capital. Tier 1 capital
must be at least 4% of total risk-weighted assets. Total capital must
be at least 8% of total risk-weighted assets. When a bank creates a
deposit to fund a loan, its assets and liabilities increase equally,
with no increase in equity. That causes its capital ratio to drop. Thus
the capital requirement limits the total amount of credit that a bank
may issue. It is important to note that the capital requirement applies
to assets while the bank reserve requirement applies to liabilities.
The China Banking Regulatory Commission (CBRC) announced new
regulations on capital adequacy on February 27 in a bid to enhance risk
management of the banking sector in line with the BIS Basel Accord.
After injecting $45 billion equity into two big state banks, China's
foreign exchange reserves stood at $403.25 billion at the end of 2003.
Under the stricter regulations, which took effect on March 1, capital
adequacy ratios of Chinese commercial banks fell further below
requirements. To give commercial banks more time to replenish their
capital base, the CBRC has set the deadline for meeting the new
requirements at January 1, 2007. Most of China's commercial banks fail
to meet the 8% minimum requirement for capital adequacy even under the
older rules, which has stood as a major obstacle hindering bank reform
efforts.
Chinese commercial banks are required to set aside part of their
profits as bad loan provisions, but few of them have been able to meet
that requirement. The vast amount of non-performing loans means, in
some cases, that some banks have to set aside more money than the net
profit they make. Under the new rules, the capital adequacy ratio -
capital divided by risk-weighted assets - is calculated after a full
deduction of bad loan provisions. Banks are required to fully set aside
reserves only after 2005. The new rules end some favorable treatment in
assigning risk weights to loans given to key state-owned enterprises
and some types of mortgage loans. The rules allow the CBRC to give
differentiated regulatory treatments to banks with different capital
adequacy levels. The CBRC has the authority to take over or urge for
restructuring of banks with "seriously low" capital adequacy ratios.
The PBoC announced on March 25 that the required reserve ratio for
financial institutions with capital adequacy ratio below a specific
level would rise 0.5% to 7.5%, while the ratio for other financial
institutions remained unchanged. State-owned commercial banks, urban
and rural credit cooperatives were exempt from the differentiated
required reserve ratio policy. On April 11, the PBoC announced again
that the required reserve ratio for all financial institutions except
from urban and rural credit cooperatives (RCC) would rise 0.5%
effective April 25. The differentiated required reserve ratio scheme
was explained as both a transitional policy in line with China's
current financial system and an innovation based on the original
purpose of required reserve ratio policy, i.e. to ensure payment and
settlement of commercial banks, and to prevent over-lending by
financial institutions attracted to profitable loan terms which may
undermine their liquidity and payment capacity. A period of one month
is hardly a reasonable transition period for bank policy changes.
The required reserve ratio policy then gradually evolved into a
monetary policy instrument and the deposit insurance regime combined
with supervision on capital adequacy ratio started to replace it as
policy tools to impose prompt corrective actions on financial
institutions based on different risk profiles. Given the fact that
China has yet to establish a deposit insurance system and quite a
number of financial institutions failed to reach the 8% capital
adequacy ratio, the differentiated required reserve ratio scheme is
conducive to curb excessive credit expansion of financial institutions
with low capital adequacy ratio and poor asset quality, and to prevent
the one-size-fits-all approach in macro financial adjustment and
regulation. Yet a one-size-fits-all approach is basic to central
banking standardization, an institutional flaw that central banks seek
to correct with complex exceptions.
At the same time, the PBoC aims to strengthen credit management by
rigorously curbing loans to over-invested industries, and keeping the
proportion of medium- and long-term loans at reasonable level. The PBoC
will also endeavor to adjust loan structure, urge financial
institutions to implement credit policy, promote financial ecological
development, enhance re-lending and rediscount management, continue to
improve and prioritize financial service to the rural economy, and
further promote inter-bank market development. These are positive moves
in support of national development, but hardly profit-driven market
strategies for private banks.
The priority of China's current interest rate policy is to enhance
institutional reform so as to facilitate monetary policy transmission
mechanism. This is a questionable priority unless institutional reform
supports national economic development. A legitimate question centers
on the validity of the assumption that a move toward market
fundamentalism enhances national economic goals. The goal of all
financial markets is to maximize private profit and in an unregulated
market, private profit maximization often runs counter to national
economic interests.
Since September 2003, the year-on-year consumer price index (CPI) level
has grown rapidly to 3.2% at the end of December, implying increasing
inflation pressure. From January to March 2004, the CPI rose 3.2%,
2.1%, and 3.1% respectively and month-to-month rose 1.1%, fell 0.2% and
rose 0.3% respectively. The CPI in the first half of this year may
continue to rise, but current one-year loan rate is 5.58%, rising 27
basis points from 5.31% after nine years. If real loan rates should
fall negative at some point in time, the behavior of market
participants will be distorted.
Already, firms can make profits simply by borrowing to acquire and hold
inventory in certain overheated sectors, thus aggravating raw material
shortage, pushing price level further up and leading funds to circulate
in retailing rather than be invested in manufacturing. Therefore, the
price level is one indicator the central bank must closely monitor when
considering interest rate policy. Yet the Chinese economy is still
highly disaggregated. Wide disparities in CPI readings are registered
in different regions and economic sectors. This leads to the question
about the validity of a unified national interest rate policy. Even in
the US, where the economy is highly aggregated, the Federal Reserve
System is comprised of 12 regional Federal Reserve Banks with 24
branches to monitor local economic conditions.
In addition, the central bank is forced to take into account the
destabilizing force of speculative foreign exchange arbitrage. Over the
past two years, capital inflows have led to a substantial rise in
China's foreign-exchange position. The amount of capital inflow is
directly linked to domestic and foreign interest rate differentials. To
deal with the problem, the PBoC adopted a floating re-lending rate
regime. Re-lending refers to the loans central bank grants to financial
institutions. Floating re-lending rate regime means the PBoC, according
to macroeconomic and financial situations, can set and announce the
extent by which the re-lending rates move above benchmark rates within
the fluctuation band authorized by the State Council.
Effective from March 25, the rates on one-year-or-less liquidity
re-lending rose by 0.63 percentage point from existing benchmark level.
In order to support agricultural development, floating re-lending rate
regime for rural credit cooperatives (RCCs) will be implemented
gradually over a period of three years, and three years later the rate
increments for RCCs will be half of those for other financial
institutions. The PBoC considers the adoption of a floating re-lending
rate regime as another important step toward interest rate
liberalization. It claims to help not only improve
the interest-rate formation mechanism and the central bank's
capability of guiding market rates, but also upgrade the effectiveness
and transparency of re-lending management. Such claims stretch monetary
logic and policy credibility.
Loan
rate resetting
Since January 1, the ways of resetting loan (excluding household
mortgages) rates are being determined by borrowers and lenders through
negotiation. The frequency of resetting rates on medium- and long-term
yuan loans, previously once a year and now determined by borrowers and
lenders, can be monthly, quarterly, annual, or fixed. This policy move
has corrected the asymmetry between fixed deposit rates and annually
changed loan rates. Consequently, commercial banks can determine the
way of resetting loan rates according to customer's credit rating, and
flexibly design loan products. Also, shortened resetting intervals help
commercial banks spot borrower solvency problems earlier. In addition,
when the central bank changes benchmark rates, commercial banks can
more promptly adjust loan rates based on lending agreements, thus
mitigating interest rate risk, facilitating the transmission of
monetary policy to manufacturing and consumption.
The change of loan rates resetting policy forced commercial banks to
establish offer system, to factor in credit risk and interest risk when
estimating profits, and to set up internal transfer pricing mechanism.
Yet often commercial banks fall into liquidity difficulties when the
central bank abruptly and unexpectedly reverses interest rate trends.
Since economic trends generally develop slowly, it would be reasonable
to expect the central bank to make its interest rate calls with minimum
element of surprise and with ample lead time. Yet central banks tend to
play cat and mouse with the market on its monetary policy moves, making
them major market-destabilizing agents.
With the control of lending scale and deposit/lending rates, the
commercial banks' asset and liability management (ALM) only focuses on
the ratio of deposit to lending. Interest rate liberalization,
nevertheless, requires commercial banks to focus on interest rate risk
and capital adequacy ratio. Loan rate floor management calls for
commercial banks to adjust asset structure with risk pricing. According
to a survey in 2002, less than half of outstanding commercial bank
lending is at fixed rate, while in publicly traded commercial banks,
the percentage of fixed rate loans is only 36. Since the
0.9-1.7-percentage-point floating range has basically liberalized
lending rates, commercial banks now must learn to price risk. This is
because China and Asia generally do not have a well-developed sovereign
credit market providing long-term sovereign debt instruments as
benchmark for bank loans and mortgages.
Bank loan pricing then must take into account such complex factors as
short-term fund cost, direct and indirect costs, loan taxation cost,
loan maturity, loan risk and profit targets. Fund cost rate refers to
the cost for commercial banks to obtain fund in the market with similar
maturity and cash flows as the loan extended to clients, i.e. the
internal transfer price of the loan. Direct costs, including all costs
related to loan product and client services, can be derived from direct
cost rate using activity-based-cost (ABC) or average-cost method.
Indirect costs, generated from operations other than loan activities,
can be calculated using the average-cost method. Because the
calculation of direct and indirect costs both use historical data, the
data must be updated regularly so as to ensure its effectiveness and
applicability.
In China, taxation cost rate is the operating tax rate plus added cost
per loan. Credit risk premium is used to cover expected loan loss and
the expected loan loss rate equals default rate multiplied by loan loss
rate. To estimate loan loss, commercial banks must set up internal
rating modes. The longer the loan's maturity, the higher should be the
lending rate. The logic behind is that longer maturity means longer
financing period, consequently higher financing cost and greater
possibility of changing cost. Therefore, the loan rates should rise
accordingly. Profit targets can be estimated using return on capital
and the ratio of capital to lending.
At present, loan pricing is one weakness of China's commercial banks
because of a history of interest rate control. In the process of
interest rate liberalization in coming years, commercial banks need to
step up efforts in pricing products, accumulate experience and develop
basic data analysis to strengthen international competitiveness. But
interest rate liberalization comes with an economic cost. The IMF has
been rightly criticized for prioritizing the soundness of lending
institutions over the health of borrowing economies by allowing
interest payments to overwhelm the budget of many borrower governments.
It is not a rational policy to destroy a national economy to save its
adventuresome banking system, much less so a foreign adventuresome
banking system.
Deposit rate ceiling management requires commercial banks to actively
adjust their liability scale and structure, and adapt themselves to
capital adequacy ratio management. Commercial banking management
theories have evolved from asset management, to liability management,
finally to asset and liability management (ALM). Liability management
for banks originated at the end of the 1960s, when high inflation and
sharp and unexpected interest rate hike combined with rigorous interest
rate control in many countries and led to disintermediation and fund
shortage in commercial banks, forcing them to adopt liability
management and to attract fund back into commercial banks through
innovation.
Bank liability management in China emerged from a very different
history. The underdevelopment of capital markets and securitization of
debt in credit markets have left banks as main intermediaries of credit
in Asia generally and China in particular. In China, funds and risks
are over-concentrated in banks while capital adequacy ratio of most
commercial banks is low. To meet capital adequacy ratio requirements,
commercial banks must reduce either asset or liability. With a deposit
rate ceiling policy, commercial banks can tailor deposit price to
specific situation. Commercial banks with low capital adequacy ratio
can reduce deposit by lowering deposit rates so as to mitigate the
pressure of excessively expanding loans to avoid loss due to large
liability. Therefore, deposit rate ceiling policy not only helps rein
in excessive credit growth and mitigate inflation pressure and
non-performing loan risks, but also guide funds into capital market to
promote capital market development and securitization. Yet savings do
not disappear merely because bank deposit rates are low; savings only
seek other vehicles to achieve higher returns. With the
underdevelopment of credit markets, an informal credit market emerges
outside of control of the central banks.
Both financial institutions and their customers need instruments to
hedge interest rate risks in a liberalized interest rate regime.
Option-pricing theory states that financial institutions, even without
derivatives, can use basic instruments to create transactions with the
same nature as derivatives to hedge risks. Derivative hedging is
cost-effective and convenient. But its advantages to the hedging
parties are derived from transfers of unit risk to systemic risk. The
nature of derivative transaction requires high leverage, a risk
reflected in the meltdown of major hedge funds such as LTCM. In this
regard, China needs to enhance fundamentally the internal control of
financial institutions before pushing toward derivative transactions to
provide commercial banks and customers with hedging instruments.
The era of $50 oil will greatly impact the global economy. Asia will be
directly affected. With the Chinese economy overheated, rising oil
price will exacerbate inflation pressures. Conventional wisdom suggests
that this adds greater pressure on interest rate rise. China is the
second largest oil consumer in the world after the US. Yet half the
Chinese demand can be met with domestic oil products. The increased
demand for imported oil comes from the expanding Chinese export sector.
High oil prices cast a shadow over global growth prospects, which could
dampen Chinese export growth and thus reduce Chinese demand for
imported oil. But since a higher price of oil increases the income of
oil producers and the expenditure of oil consumers for the same amount
of oil, high oil price increases world GDP without expanding the world
economy. High oil prices are inflationary on a global scale.
Chinese export growth can transform into market share growth even as
the global economy slows down. As China's global market share in export
expands, the value-adding performance of its trade will correspondingly
be upgraded even if global economic growth slows. High oil price has
limited direct impact on Chinese domestic consumption since domestic
consumption is supplied mostly by domestic production. So far, domestic
inflation pressure has mainly come from food and farm produce prices.
But oil prices are global. Chinese domestic oil will seek export
markets if domestic prices stay below world market levels, unless price
control is instituted. Rising prices in imported oil and oil products
and other basic commodities affect mostly capital industries and the
real estate sector. The manufacturing sector registered no inflation
for lack of pricing power due to overcapacity, even though energy cost
has increased. Cost-pushed inflation in the export sector has been
largely neutralized by reduced profit margins and productivity
increases from worker reduction and salary decreases.
Oil
and yuan
The high oil price has refocused the debate on the yuan exchange rate.
An upward revaluation of the yuan may temporarily reduce the nominal
cost of imported oil, but the resultant fall in the dollar will lead
oil producers to further raise oil prices. The US has adopted a "benign
neglect" posture on the falling dollar for devious reasons. And the
chairman of the Fed actually began to "talk down" the dollar. The
European Central Bank is caught in a dilemma. Since oil is denominated
in dollars, a high euro will help the eurozone on energy cost and
help contain euro inflation and keep euro interest rates low. As it is,
all central banks are trying to keep short-term interest rate below
neutrality because of high unemployment everywhere. A falling dollar
will also reduce windfall profits for the Organization of
Petroleum Exporting Countries. The US will keep oil around $50, which
is good for oil-producing states such as Texas; keep the Europeans
quiet about a falling dollar, increase US exports to keep the labor
unions under control, defuse mounting isolationism in Congress and make
it cheaper to foreigners to invest in dollar assets, keeping dollar
asset prices up. There is no incentive for Washington to alleviate
international tension if that will bring the dollar up. Thus the
monetary argument for multilateralism is also disarmed.
China has an unbalanced, overheated economy, with some serious
over-investment in some sectors and regions while other sectors and
regions are caught in protracted stagnation and credit crunch. The key
to the Chinese economy lies in rebalancing export with domestic
development and shifting investment from overheated regions to
depressed underdeveloped regions. This shift requires policy planning
to rein in unregulated markets and to apply national banking principles
to domestic development. Doctrinaire central banking in support of
capital markets for maximum return on capital at the expense of
national development must be curbed. Improved risk-management systems
alone will not cure the problem of excess liquidity pouring into
unauthorized steel mills, aluminum smelters and real-estate projects,
causing an inflationary investment bubble. Planned credit allocation
needs to be strengthened in keeping with the Five-Year Plan, which has
been largely ignored by blind faith in market fundamentalism. China had
139,400 building projects under construction in the first seven months
of 2004, with total investment rising 38% to 11.2 trillion yuan, most
of which were located in over-saturated markets in overheated regions.
No amount of bank risk management can withstand such massive scale of
credit-market failure.
Give
credit where due
Credit allocation is not related to the level of interest rates in a
planned economy. In the US, credit allocation is handled with tax
deductibility of interest payment in government-encouraged sectors.
Much of the credit misallocation in China has been created by its state
privatization policy to rely on a market economy for economic growth.
This unleashes massive off-budget spending financed with loans from
newly privatized banks based on unrealistic revenue projections. Such
privatization activities have contributed to the concentrated surge in
domestic loan demand in saturated markets. When economic growth slows,
these loans will turn non-performing. The overheating in the Chinese
economy is concentrated along the coastal region, with the rest of the
nation left underdeveloped for lack of credit. It is also concentrated
in proliferation of copycat projects of earlier entrepreneurial
successes.
The Chinese Ministry of Finance had announced that starting October 1,
1999, interest payment to bank depositors would be taxed at an annual
rate of 20% nationwide. This action ended four decades of tax-free
interest income. It defies common sense for Xinqiang to have the same
interest tax rate as Shanghai if the government promotes a policy to
shift investment to the interior west.
China's total tax revenue is less than 12% of GDP, one of the lowest in
the world. This is the residual legacy of a socialist economy in which
tax revenue is not crucial for financing public expenditure. The use of
sovereign credit for domestic development is conditioned on the
principle of the State Theory of Money, which asserts that the value of
a fiat currency rests on government authority to tax. In shifting to a
"socialist market economy", China is under-taxed for the full
application of sovereign credit for domestic development. This fact
limits the ability of the central government to plan for balanced
national development. And the Chinese economy is still highly
disaggregated by location. Unlike the US, where the states enjoy
substantial power to set local tax policies to compete for growth,
Chinese provinces are allotted very limited autonomous authority in
this regard. Thus the depressed, low-growth regions constantly find
themselves at a disadvantaged competitive position compared to the
coastal, developed ones.
Higher interest rates across the whole economy affect not only
overheated sectors and regions, but also underperforming sectors and
regions. China's agriculture and service industries have received less
investment compared with natural resource sectors closely related to
the export sector and the real estate sector in coastal cities. While
fixed-asset investments grew 40%, year-on-year during the year's first
quarter, investments in the nation's agriculture sector rose a scanty
0.4%.
China's service sector has not shown any sign of overheating. In fact,
education and health services have experienced declining investment for
more than two decades. Since private investments are expected by policy
to gradually replace government spending as the economy's main driving
force, high interest rates will cause credit crunches on fund-strapped
sectors while having little influence on already-overheated sectors.
China's policymakers have been unduly and unwisely influenced by Hong
Kong capitalists whose experience has been limited to real estate and
light manufacturing and have not the slightest clue on national
economic development policy.
By the end of June, bank loans to the real-estate sector reached 2.1
trillion yuan, up 36.1% year-on-year. New investments in land
developments increased 28.7%. A recent field survey by the National
Bureau of Statistics indicated the average property price in 35 of
China's cities increased 10.4% in the year's second quarter compared
with a year ago. In Shanghai, the growth figure reached an astonishing
20%. In industries supporting real estate construction such as steel,
cement and building supplies, fixed investment is as high as 172% (iron
and steel). Official government estimates say that when all steel
projects currently under construction come to full production, they
will turn out more steel in 2005 than the country will be able to use
until 2010.
Despite the central government tightening regulations in the steel,
cement and aluminum sectors, the real estate sector drove steel prices
up 2.1% in July from June, and 18% from a year ago. The price of cement
rose 4.7% from June, and 11.6% year-on-year. The PBoC noted in its 2004
third-quarterly report on monetary policy that its credit-tightening
measures have prevented new investments in the real-estate sector, but
failed to influence the demand side. As investments and new projects in
land development continue to decline, demand will consequently exceed
supply. This will push property prices up. But the demand side in the
real estate sector can be managed in ways besides interest rate hikes,
such as increasing down payment ratio for residential mortgages to
effectively bring down property prices.
But the real factor behind price inflation in real estate is not
construction cost, but rising land cost, a factor over which the
central bank commands no direct control. Investments in real estate
grew by more than 40% in the first quarter year-on-year. This is the
fastest growth in China's modern history - almost three times the
25-year average of 15%. What this means is that investors are pouring
money into real estate, which is jacking up prices and creating an
artificial bubble just waiting to pop. Figures from the end of 2003
estimate that real-estate vacancies stand at 26%, quadruple the US
figure, eight times Hong Kong's and two and a half times the
international norm. The inventory cannot possibly be absorbed by
domestic consumers whose income cannot support such speculative prices.
These prices are sustained by speculative momentum.
Yet the recent interest rate hikes in the US are unlikely to cause an
outflow of speculative funds, or hot money, from China. Martin
Feldstein, president of the National Bureau of Economic Research and
Harvard professor of economics, has calculated that a 0.25% or even a
1% increase in dollar interest rate will not make hot money leave
China. This is because China's rigid currency regime and tight control
over capital accounts means speculative funds will, over the short
term, have trouble finding a way to benefit from the abrupt rate rises
in the US. A short-term rate change would not affect foreign direct
investments (FDI) going into China as FDI is generally for the long
term. On the other hand, a widely expected US long-term policy of a
measured pace of interest rate hikes will force interest rates in other
currencies to rise.
China's GDP still grew 9.8% in the first quarter of 2004. Fixed asset
investment reached 879.9 billion yuan, up 43% year-on-year. The April
consumer price index (CPI) also jumped to 3.8%, compared with 2.8% for
the first quarter. Money supply in the first quarter grew 17% and new
loans reached 2.6 trillion yuan, the second highest in history. Yet
amid these bullish growth data, unemployment keeps rising. Also in
April, construction of a major steel smelting facility in Jiangsu
province was brought to a screeching halt for alleged illegal land
expropriation and improper borrowing. The move was widely viewed as
part of the effort to halt undesirable construction in an overheated
sector. The State Development and Reform Commission also conducted a
nationwide price inspection. Local governments were instructed to halt
utility price hikes if inflation in their areas exceeded national
norms.
Financial institutions lent 1.88 trillion yuan in the first seven
months of 2004, already topping the total for loans in 2002. Interest
rates have soared after the release of these data. The rate on
benchmark seven-day repurchase agreements jumped to above 2.8%, even
higher than the 2.66% coupon on a seven-year sovereign bond issue
earlier in 2004. The problem is that these loans have been made in the
wrong sectors and to the wrong borrowers.
PBoC has already reversed a contractive stance it maintained for the
first eight months of 2004 in open market operations, releasing 35
billion yuan of currency in repurchase agreements in September. The CPI
is expected to rise less than 1%. The auto and real estate sectors,
where prices have been growing the fastest, are currently not factored
in China's CPI. Both sectors appear to be heading for abrupt slowdowns
due to dwindling purchasing power. And the ex-factory prices for
consumer goods, which largely dictate CPI trends, have been on the
decline in 2004. The CPI, after months of decline, started to rise in
October 2003, hitting 1% in April, but subsided afterwards. It
registered 0.5% rise in August 2004. Little noticed is that fact the
CPI declines often comes from declining corporate profits.
The growing investments are partly the result of years of low
investment, fueled by heavy initial investments in such sectors as
automobiles, and may be offset by the sluggishness in spending. Since
August, China's macroeconomic policy makers have faced a dilemma:
either fail in cooling down the economy or risk causing economic
depression. The official jobless rate is 4.3% that does not reflect the
real situation since it does not include laid-off workers from
state-owned industries or migrant workers. Even though Chinese workers
earn on average $0.61 an hour, China is losing manufacturing jobs
because of technological advances as employers try to boost
productivity by laying off redundant workers, given that wages cannot
fall below zero. Unskilled workers can become cost-ineffective against
the cost of automation. Evidence is mounting that job shrinkage can
also occur on low wage levels in a booming economy.
Fixed-asset investment in China rose 26.3% year-on-year in August 2004,
down from 31.1% in July and far below the 47.8% in the first quarter.
Other key data shows a similar trend. Industrial output rose 15.9%
year-on-year, slightly above a 15.5% rise the month before but well
below the 19.4% first-quarter growth rate. M2 money growth hit a 3
1/2-year low in September, growing 13.6%. Household savings deposits
grew 14.9% in the month, considerably down from a January peak of
20.5%. The Asian Development Bank forecasts a 13% increase in domestic
consumption in 2005 as urban and rural incomes keep rising. Signs that
inflation has peaked, growing 5.3% in August - unchanged from July -
were also welcomed by economists. It was the first time since February
that price rises have not accelerated. Thus while growth is still at a
high rate, the trend has slowed.
Still
hot
Concern is now shifting from fear of a hard landing to concern that
growth will soon accelerate again as the restrictive measures gradually
lose their initial impact. The corporate sector can work its way around
administrative measures as they draw from their past experience at
evading them. Continued foreign direct investment, rising inflation and
anecdotal information on distribution bottlenecks suggest that the
economy is not cooling down, at least in the intended sectors. The last
thing the Chinese economy needs now is a slow down in consumer spending
while capital spending continues.
China's new rural cooperative medical system has benefited more than 95
million people since it was implemented last year. Still, that amounts
only to less than 1% of China's rural population. The new system is
mainly used to help farmers who are impoverished by illness and to
reimburse costly treatment and hospitalization expenses. The funds come
from the central government budget, local government subsidies and
farmers' tax payments. By the end of September, the funds amounted to
three billion yuan, which translates into $3.50 per capita benefit
recipient. The new system is expected to cover all the country's rural
areas by 2010.
With threatening over-investments, the PBoC warned that it "could
inflame inflation or asset price bubble, resulting in new
non-performing loans and financial risks", those financial risks being
mass bankruptcies as the result of market oversupply. Much of this
excessive investment is going into blind investment and duplicate
construction, which pose the same risks. Blind investment finds banks
and independent investors throwing money at some projects or industries
without any risk assessment, or just following the herd instinct into a
booming, but potentially disastrous, market. Duplicate construction
means jumping on some bandwagon and over-investing in industries
already saturated. For example, the Zhujiang area in Guangdong has
eight airports in a region the size of Massachusetts and Connecticut.
In addition, local governments fall all over each other to establish
special economic zones, but 43% of the land in such zones remains
unused, with no revenue to service the loans spent to build the
enabling infrastructure.
Curbing bank lending and reining in bad and redundant investments do
not address the structural causes that have led to these problems. In
1993, similar measures led to a severe recession, deflation and
insolvent banks. Yet market forces have become stronger in the Chinese
economy now than in 1993; and the rate and scale of investment are much
greater today because of hot money inflow. For example, profits on
investments in the steel industry increased by more than 100%
year-on-year in the first two months of 2004.
By calculating China's trade revenue against its total foreign
reserves, the amount of hot money flowing into the country in the first
quarter this year may amount to as much as $30.9 billion, or an
increase of 25.6% over last year, when China's foreign reserves
increased by 57%. The central bank needs to sterilize foreign exchange
reserves by selling treasury bonds and to sell more treasury bonds, it
will have to raise interest rates. This only encourages more hot money
as speculators change their dollars to yuan in anticipation of a
revaluation, collecting higher interest rates until they can sell back
their yuan at a profit. Meanwhile, China's economy continues to
overheat with over-investment in saturated export sectors, while
inflation ravages other under-invested domestic sectors.
Administratively, the government has done all it can do within the
limits of a market economy and the economy is still overheating. The
loan curb, the projects halts, the rise in bank reserve requirement and
the interest rate rise have not reduced overheating in the export
sectors, but have created mounting stress in the domestic sectors. It
has been suggested that a 10-15% revaluation of the yuan would take
speculative pressure off the currency immediately, and foreign money
coming into the country to invest in overheated industries would slow
overnight because speculators would get fewer yuan for their dollar. At
the same time, such a revaluation would restore flexibility in managing
both fiscal and monetary policy, enabling policymakers to raise
interest rates without consequences on hot money flow. But high
interest rate will cause an immediate burst of the ongoing hot money
bubble, making the cure worse than the disease.
Some have suggested that the yuan should be removed from its peg to the
dollar and repegged to a currency basket weighted on the currencies of
China's major trading partners. This would supposedly maintain the
equilibrium value of the yuan in a dynamic global economy. Once the
yuan is re-pegged, and a new reference basket implemented, any
additional moves, such as widening the trading band, could be phased in
during a transition period of some years. This would supposedly provide
a safe and effective path to a more flexible exchange rate regime. But
dollar hegemony renders such scheme inoperative. The exchange value of
the yuan is only the symptom and not the cause of the problem. The
problem is that under dollar hegemony, trade surplus ships wealth to
the dollar economy in the form of added dollar reserves and trade
deficits ship wealth to the dollar economy in the form of dollar debts.
Either way, exporting for dollar is a losing game for the non-dollar
exporting economies.
To guard against possible risks, Chinese regulators have launched a
probe into foreign exchange acceptance and settlement operations by
commercial banks. The State Administration of Foreign Exchange (SAFE)
said it would clamp down on illegal cross-border capital flows. An
effective mechanism to more closely monitor the flow of speculative
capital in and out of the country is urgently needed. For more than 18
months, speculators both inside and outside China have been betting
that the yuan will appreciate sharply against the US dollar.
But a significant appreciation now appears less likely. The
constellation of forces that made yuan appreciation appears unavoidable
have now shifted their alignment. China's current account is in deficit
so far this year and rising, suggesting that from a trade
competitiveness perspective, the yuan is not undervalued on a global
basis. The yuan is not even undervalued to the dollar since much of the
US current account deficit is a structural component of dollar
hegemony, not just an overvalued currency. In addition, much of what
China wants to buy from the US, particularly high-tech products, is
banned from sale by US policy. Yet a rise in yuan interest rate was
also considered unlikely until it surprisingly became reality.
The changing dynamics surrounding inflow of hot money is a big part of
total capital inflow. China's capital inflows are different from those
suffered by South-East Asian stock markets in the run-up to the
financial crisis of 1997. The speculative funds entering China have not
been destined for domestic stock markets but rather for the
construction and real estate sectors. Since April, China has issued a
series of administrative orders to cool down construction and property
investments. Some projects have been stopped and others have found bank
financing drying up. The cumulative effect has been that hot money is
finding it increasingly difficult to find profitable projects.
Hot money inflows have averaged between $10 billion to $13 billion a
month this year. This, in turn, could mean that China's foreign
currency reserves may start to expand less quickly month after month.
This trend may convince speculators that pressures on the yuan to
revalue are dissipating. A slowdown in the growth of China's foreign
reserves means that China will be buying less US debts, creating
problem for the US debt bubble and causing dollar interest rates to
rise, thus reducing dollar hot money from leaving the US.
A sustained drop in foreign central bank purchases of US debts could
add to pressures on the US Federal Reserve to raise interest rates at a
faster pace. That could support the US dollar's value against other
currencies, thereby bringing the yuan up with it. But high dollar
interest rate can abort the anemic recovery of the US economy. The
alternative facing the Fed is that it will have no option except to
inject more liquidity into the dollar money supply, by keeping dollar
interest rates below neutral, accepting inflation as growth. Some of
the excess dollar liquidity will find its way into China as hot money.
Central bank officials have repeatedly said that China will continue to
lift foreign exchange control to balance trade and gradually make the
yuan a freely convertible currency. The floating of yuan exchange rate
was an objective set at the Third Plenary Session of the Fourteenth
Central Committee of the Communist Party of China in 1993, more than a
decade ago. But the process is expected to take a relatively long time.
China has already taken a series of measures to make exchange under
current account easier and to liberalize restrictions on capital
account transactions. However, trade liberalization, removal of
excessive restrictions on capital account transactions and reform of
state-owned commercial banks need to be accomplished before adequate
flexibility can be introduced in the exchange rate regime. The
difficulties and destabilizing effects of these moves tend to justify
even more gradualism. The last thing China needs is to repeat Russia's
disastrous shock-treatment market liberalization, from which the former
superpower never recovered.
Nothing
to gain
As foreign-funded financial institutions will be permitted under the
terms of the World Trade Organization (WTO) to conduct yuan business
and substantially broaden their market access in China by 2006, Chinese
state-owned commercial banks need time to strengthen their
competitiveness and risk-prevention mechanism to viably response to a
new exchange rate regime. The prospect of Chinese commercial banks
being ready for international competition within two years is almost
zero. On the other hand, the prospect of a global financial crisis
caused by dollar hegemony before 2006 is very high. Those within the
Chinese policy establishment who opposed China's entry into WTO may
have their warnings vindicated. With the global financial system on the
verge of collapse, isolationism is not an extremist position.
If an adjustment of the yuan exchange rate makes China's staple
agricultural products uncompetitive with imports, farmers, especially
those in the coastal regions, will be forced to migrate to cities in a
much higher rate, making non-farm employment demand more acute in
cities. A one-percentage-point fall in agricultural employment
translates to a need of 4 million additional non-farm jobs. The head of
the PBoC has said that given the size and development stage of China
economy, the prevailing exchange rate regime has been working quite
well. Between 1994 and 1997, the exchange rate of the yuan against the
dollar appreciated from 8.7 to 8.3, reflecting a managed float regime.
At the end of 1997, at the request of neighboring economies and
international institutions, China substantially narrowed the floating
band of the yuan exchange rate to help reduce the shock of the Asian
financial crisis and dispel the fear of yuan devaluation. Yet, the
central bank's view is that with the role of the market becoming
increasingly important in the Chinese economy, the exchange rate of the
yuan will increasingly be determined by market forces.
Although it was not expected that China would respond automatically to
the recent dollar interest rate hikes, the PBoC did raise interest rate
amid concerns about rising prices. On September 15, 2003, the Chinese
government issued 2.4 billion yuan of sovereign debt. China has adopted
aggressive financial policies over the past five years to alleviate
deflationary and unemployment pressures. This has led to a sizable
fiscal deficit that must be made up for by issuing sovereign debt. Last
year, China issued a total of 592.9 billion yuan of sovereign debt.
According to official Chinese estimates, this year will see the issue
of 637.6 billion yuan of sovereign debt. Increasing market interest
rates will lead to a fall in price of sovereign debt, which will be
disadvantageous to the issue of sovereign debt to make up for huge
budget deficits. This will make aggressively tight monetary policies
difficult.
China wishes to maintain a fixed exchange rate in order to maintain
export competitiveness and avoid deflation, but is doing so by creating
a sharp increase in the issue of money, which may lead to an overheated
bubble economy, increasing the amount of non-performing loans and
systemic financial risk. China therefore wants to tighten money supply
by slowing the rate at which money is issued and suppressing inflation.
However, this may in turn lead to higher interest rates and increase
the cost of monetary policy implementation, while at the same time
possibly increasing the rate at which speculative hot money enters the
country, thereby increasing the pressure on the yuan to appreciate.
Higher interest rates will lead to falling consumption and investment
across the entire economy, which will further aggravate China's still
very serious deflationary problem in key domestic sectors. The
government must therefore actively increase fiscal expenditure. Such is
the difficult dilemma currently faced by Chinese policymakers.
China has posted price increases for some industrial goods while others
have been leveling off. Declining steel prices as a result of
oversupply are especially a concern. Overall, prices of industrial
goods leaving the factory, measured by the producer price index (PPI),
edged up 0.7% in April 2004 over March and rose 9.3% over the same
month a year earlier. Prices for most basic commodities such as food,
minerals and fuel continued to rise, while those for consumer goods
like television, washing machine and refrigerator fell. Propped up by
food and raw material price increases, China's consumer price index
rose a modest 2.8% year-on-year from January to March.
The Chinese government has set a 3% CPI increase target for 2004 and
the central bank predicted that the index would continue to climb after
April because of the "spill-over" factor and a lower comparative base
from the same 2003 period, when the Chinese economy was hit by the SARS
outbreak, but the CPI is expected to fall starting from the third
quarter. Nationwide investment in fixed assets, including capital
projects and factory equipment, soared an annualized 43% in the first
quarter, which the central bank blamed partly on some departments and
local governments neglecting central government calls and keeping
investment robust to score political points. Banks loaned 835.1 billion
yuan in the first quarter, representing 32% of the annual target and an
increase of 24.7 billion yuan from a year ago. The outstanding broad
money, or M2, including money in circulation and all deposits, surged
19.1% year-on-year to 23.36 trillion yuan by the end of April. The
increase was almost equal to that of March.
By tightening the monetary policy, the central bank said its annual
targets - letting both M2 and M1 grow 17% and commercial banks' lending
add 2.6 trillion yuan - could be reached. It said the impact of its
policy initiatives such as higher bank reserve requirement and open
market operations, including issue of central bank bills and treasury
bonds trade - would be felt later. To brake the economy is not the task
confined to the central bank. The State Development and Reform
Commission recently issued a regulation on controlling rush investments
and clearing away copycat projects; the ministry of land and resources
recovered more than half of China's 6,015 development zones last year
and has stopped approving new such zones. The international pressure to
revalue the yuan is becoming more an issue of political concern than of
economic significance.
China's agriculture and service industries have received less
investment compared with sectors related to natural resources and the
industries closely associated with the real estate sector. While
fixed-asset investments grew 40% year-on-year during the first quarter,
investments in agriculture rose only 0.4%. China's service sector has
not shown any sign of overheating. By the end of June, bank loans to
the real estate sector had reached 2.1 trillion yuan, up 36.1%
year-on-year. New investments in land development increased 28.7%.
A recent field survey by the National Bureau of Statistics indicated
the average property price in 35 of China's cities increased 10.4% in
the second quarter compared with a year ago. In Shanghai, the growth
figure reached an astonishing 20%. In July, steel prices rose 2.1% from
June, up 18% from a year ago. Price of cement rose 4.7% from June, and
11.6% year-on-year. With inflation on the rise, China is quickly
slipping into negative interest rates. A negative interest rate over a
long period would inevitably deter people from putting their money into
banks. In the second quarter, only 32.2% of those surveyed have
recently chosen to put more savings in banks, 2.5 and 1.1 percentage
points lower than the figures in the first quarter this year and the
same period last year.
Many people chose to invest in financial assets other than bank
deposits. Investment funds served as a main channel for diversified
household savings. In the first half of this year, net value of
investment funds increased 132.4 billion yuan, 126.8 billion yuan more
than the same period last year. A rebound in the stock market,
especially in the first four months of this year, has amplified the
diversion of funds from personal bank accounts. As of the end of July,
71.57 million folks had investment accounts in China's two stock
exchanges, in Shanghai and Shenzhen, 1.86 million more than the same
period last year. In the first half of this year, domestic stock
investment amounted to 35.6 billion yuan, 11.4 billion yuan more than a
year ago.
A higher interest rate on treasury bonds compared to bank deposits also
lured investors. In the first six months of the year, the ministry of
finance issued five certificate treasury bonds with a total household
investment of 122.7 billion yuan, 114.3 billion yuan more than the same
period last year. Investment in insurance also diverted household
savings, with investment volume in life insurance hitting 178.8 billion
yuan within the first six months, 11 billion yuan more than the figure
in the first half 2003. Altogether, household investment in stocks,
funds, treasury and enterprise bonds, and insurance totaled 482 billion
yuan in the first half, 262.6 billion yuan more, or 1.2 times the
figure, compared to the same period last year.
Increased consumption also contributed to the drop in household
savings. Sputtering increases of demand has been a prominent problem in
the Chinese economy in recent years. This year, total retail sales
increased 2.95 trillion yuan in the first seven months, a year-on-year
increase of 12.8%. Deducting price factors, the increase was 4.5
percentage points higher than that of the same period of 2003. There is
generally an inverse relationship between consumer spending and
household savings.
For a given supply of money, an increase in the production of goods
will increase the exchange value of a currency since each unit will buy
more goods. Likewise, increasing the supply of money relative to a
fixed output of goods will lead to a decline in the purchasing power of
money with each currency unit buying fewer goods. Given the relatively
high rate of growth in China's money supply, there could be
considerable pressures for the yuan to depreciate. This is because a
rate of growth of the money supply that exceeds the growth rate of
economic activity tends to cause the rate of exchange to fall. Even if
exchange rates are fixed but capital can move freely, capital flight
from the country tends to put pressures to end loose monetary policies.
When exchange rates are determined by supply and demand, imbalances can
continue for a long time only if most central banks coordinate their
policy stances. Once they stop following similar monetary policies, the
exchange value of a currency can drop sharply. In the worst case, the
collapse of the exchange rate can trigger a severe shock to the real
side of the domestic economy. What is happening with respect to
international valuations of the dollar at the moment is that US central
bankers are pumping dollars into the dollar economy to finance US trade
deficits. That forces US trading partners to pump local currencies in
their economies through foreign reserves transmission. But the
additional dollars is recycled into dollar debts and stay in the dollar
economy. Thus the dollar economy grows faster than the US economy. So
the dollar will continue to weaken as long as the rate of increase in
new dollars into the dollar economy is greater than the growth of the
US economy. Dollar hegemony prevents non-dollar central banks from
pumping more local currencies into the economy. Under such conditions,
equilibrium between the dollar economy and the US economy can only be
maintained with the continued fall of the exchanged value of the
dollar.
What China needs to do is to raise wages, not interest rates, to
increase consumer spending. It is of course plausible that at some
point spending could outgrow the economy's capacity to produce, causing
prices to accelerate to unacceptable levels. Economists have labeled
the unemployment rate below which this inflationary spiral would
theoretically ignite as the NAIRU, or the non-accelerating-inflation
rate of unemployment. In the early 1990s, the conventional wisdom among
economists, including most at the Federal Reserve, was that the
unemployment rate could not go below 6% without triggering an
accelerating rate of inflation. The few economists who pointed out that
there was little empirical evidence to support this theory and that the
economy could achieve non-inflationary unemployment rates of 4% or even
lower were derided by the profession and ignored by the business media.
The US unemployment rate has now been below 6% since September 1994,
below 5% since June 1997, and below 4.5% since April 1998. Core
inflation has not only not accelerated, it remains dormant. The NAIRU
is revealed as useless as a guide to economic policy. Every episode of
accelerating inflation in the US since 1960 was led by prices, not by
wages. The current effort to slow down the Chinese economy, therefore,
appears to be targeted at weakening the bargaining position of labor
against capital. Throughout the economic expansion of last decade,
wages have fallen behind corporate profits in every economy of the
world, including China and the US. In the US, economist Jared Bernstein
has calculated that even if labor costs were to accelerate to rising 1%
faster than productivity, it would take four years before wages and
profits went back to their respective shares in the decade of the
1980s.
In moving toward a socialist market economy, China can benefit from
lessons learned in the US New Deal. The National Industrial Recovery
Act aimed to stabilize industrial prices, raise wages and promote
collective bargaining, while the Agriculture Adjustment Act aimed to
raise farm prices. These measures were combined with measures for
reforming banking and financial practices and increasing the supply of
money and credit. The New Deal also appropriated large sums for direct
relief for the poor and the unemployed and for a massive public works
program. Unfortunately, both acts were struck down by a conservative
Supreme Court as unconstitutional, which fortunately is not a problem
for China. But to do that, China must first insulate its currency from
dollar hegemony and relieve its economic growth from excessive
dependence on export for dollars.
|