Critique of Central Banking
By
Henry C K Liu
Part I: Monetary
theology
Part II:
The European experience
This article appeared in AToL
on November 8, 2002
During the rise of Europe in past centuries, industrial progress was
not made in a free-market system, but in a government-support system
that provided investment capital through national banking. There are
undeniable data showing that any nation that did not adopt a
government-financed industrial policy had failed to develop as an
economic or military power in the 17th, 18th and 19th centuries.
The idea of a national bank in modern times began in the
Netherlands.
Key to the success of the Dutch economy in the 17th century was the
Amsterdam Wisselbank, which had been founded in 1609 to provide credit
to the city of Amsterdam, to the province of Holland and to trade
through the funding of the monopolistic Dutch East India Company.
Wisselbank was also responsible for coinage and exchange. Some seven
decades later, in 1683, it was further empowered to lend to private
clients. All large payments had to pass through Wisselbank and it
therefore was convenient for the major finance houses to bank with it.
Thus not only was it in a position to oversee the Dutch financial
scene, it was also able to act as a stabilizing influence. Its function
was exclusively to enhance Dutch national financial interests and, in
that sense, it was different from private banking, which sought profit
wherever opportunities existed within the law.
By the middle of the 17th century, the notion of a national
bank to
provide needed liquidity to finance national economic development and
expanding trade had gathered support in England. The perception of
credit as the seed of wealth creation in a capitalistic system was
gaining acceptance, leading to an awareness that money, if backed by
the state, needed no intrinsic value to enable it to be useful in
fueling and lubricating the economy. The concept of a sovereign or
national debt being financed with paper money issued by fiat, backed
ultimately by national wealth, to support national purposes, especially
war, gradually gained recognition.
The Dutch model of national banking inspired the Bank of
England,
founded in 1694 by William Paterson, a Scotsman, with a capital of
STG1.2 million, backed by gold, which was simultaneously advanced (to
finance the war with France) to William III (1650-1702), who had been
crowned with Mary by the Glorious Revolution of 1688-89, which marked
the triumph of parliamentary authority over royal absolutism. The
capital/loan came from a syndicate of private investors/lenders who, in
return for holding government bonds, were given the privilege of
operating a national bank. This was the origin of British national
banking and the national debt, which had not been necessary under
absolutism because the sovereign had absolute command of all wealth in
the royal realm. The Bank of England managed the government's accounts
and made loans to finance public spending at times of peace or war.
Operating also as a commercial bank, it took deposits and issued notes.
John Law (1671-1729), Scottish economist, gambler, banker and
royal
adviser, was renowned for two remarkable enterprises he created in
France: the Banque Generale and the Mississippi Scheme. His economic
legacy rests on two major concepts: the scarcity theory of value and
the Real Bills Doctrine of money.
Exiled from Britain for participating in an illegal, fatal
duel, Law
found himself welcome in the French court through the patronage and
friendship of Philippe, the Duke of Orleans, regent of France during
the minority of Louis XV. Despite being a nation of greater wealth than
either Britain or the Netherlands, the state of French finances after
Louis XIV's death in 1715 was so dismal, because of France's neglect in
leveraging its national wealth through banking and credit, that the
regent eagerly accepted Law's proposal to establish in 1716 a
state-chartered bank, the Banque Generale, with the power to issue
paper currency. Concurrently, Law also founded the Mississippi Company,
an enterprise intended for developing the then French colony of
Louisiana in North America.
Law was granted a charter to create the Banque Generale with
a capital
of 6 million livres, of which he raised 25 percent in cash and covered
the remaining 4.5 million livres with government debt (billets
d'etat) trading at only one-fourth of its face value. Law's Banque
Generale was authorized to issue interest-paying bank notes payable in
silver on demand. It soon had 60 million livres in notes outstanding.
The Regime required regional tax payments to be in the form of Banque
Generale banknotes to provide a ready market for them. Because these
banknotes paid interest and were conveniently acceptable as for tax
payment, they sold at a premium over their face value, removing from
the state seigniorage (government revenue from the manufacturing of
coins calculated as the difference between the monetary and the bullion
value of the silver contained in silver coins) and delivering it to the
speculative market. That was a major error, for interest payment turned
the national banknotes into a debt instrument, indistinguishable from a
government bond but with no fixed maturity.
To develop the territories of Louisiana in North America, Law
was
granted a charter for the Compagnie de l'Occident with a 25-year lease
on French holdings in Louisiana. In return, the Compagnie was required
to settle at least 6,000 French citizens and 3,000 slaves in the
territories. The Compagnie was also granted a monopoly on the growing
and sale of tobacco. The Compagnie acquired the Compagnie de Senegal,
which operated in West Africa, as a source of slaves. It then merged
with the French East India Company and the French China Company to form
Compagnie des Indes, forming a virtual monopoly on French foreign
trade.
Law's Banque Generale, under the new name of Banque Royale,
tying it
closer to the state, was added to a monopolistic combination that Law
called the "System".
The Compagnie des Indes issued 200,000 shares at a per share
price of
500 livres in 1716. By 1718 the share price had fallen to 250 livres.
In 1719, the Banque Royale pumped up the supply of notes by 30 percent.
It also acquired the right to act as the national tax collector for
nine years. The Compagnie stock doubled and redoubled in price.
Based on new financial power from inflated market
capitalization, Law
then offered a plan to pay off the troublesome state debt, committing
another fundamental error. The Banque would issue notes paying 3
percent interest to redeem the state debt. The banknotes could then be
used to buy stock in Law's Compagnie de Indes. The Compagnie share
price rose to 5,000 livres in August 1719 and 8,000 livres in October.
Speculation in Compagnie stock went wild, much like the dot-com shares
in the 1990s. Stock was being purchased on 90 percent margin. Fortunes
were being made overnight by speculators, with a street beggar
reportedly making 70 million livres.
John Law became an international celebrity. The pope sent an
envoy to
the birthday party of Law's daughter. Law converted to Catholicism and
was appointed controlleur des finances by the Regime.
Compagnie des Indes shares peaked at a per share price of
20,000 livres
at the end of 1719. In January 1720, two royal princes decided to cash
in their shares of the Compagnie, prompting others to follow. Law had
to print 1.5 million livres in paper money to meet the rising demand
for cash. As controlleur des finances, he tried to stem the
tide by making it illegal to hold more than 500 livres in gold or
silver. He devalued banknotes relative to foreign currency to encourage
exports and discourage imports. Nevertheless Compagnie des Indes stock
fell to 5,000 livres. As head of both the Compagnie des Indes and the
Banque Royale, Law bought up stocks and banknotes to try to raise their
price, but by June 1720 he had to suspend all payments.
Law's note-issuing bank fell from being a spectacular success
to total
collapse after a panic bank run in 1720, plunging France and Europe
into a severe economic crisis, which set the economic stage for the
French Revolution. The impact of Law's banking schemes on France was so
traumatic that, until recently, the term banque was largely
shunned by French banks in order to avoid memories of Law's unfortunate
institution. The common substitute term was credit, as in
Credit Lyonnais and Credit Agricole.
In England, a similar scheme known as the South Sea Bubble
also burst
at the same time, but the South Sea Company and its banker, the Bank of
England, was bailed out by the government through the British national
debt, for which the people of Britain assumed responsibility and which
was made credible by parliamentary control of finance. The failure of
the French national bank was caused by its tie merely to whimsical
royal credit rather than reliable national credit. The failure left
France without an adequate banking system until Napoleon Bonaparte,
who, to replenish the nearly empty state treasury, transformed the Bank
of Current Accounts into the Banque de France on January 28, 1800, as
the first French national bank.
Napoleon III, whom historians saw as the prototype of the
modern
dictator, was labeled the bourgeois emperor by royalists and the
socialist emperor by the Saint Simonians, who were among the first in
modern history to conceive a centrally planned industrial system, and
who invented investment banking. Under him the Credit Mobilier was
founded in 1852, established specifically for providing funds for
industry and infrastructure, and followed by other banks. Despite the
failure of the Credit Mobilier in 1867, these investment banks
channeled savings into essential investments in transport,
communication, agriculture and industry.
In 1860, Credit Agricole was founded to supply credit for
French
agriculture in its transformation from feudal estates into a modern
economic sector. Credit Agricole eventually developed into one of the
world's largest banks, supplying financing to the largest agricultural
producer in Europe. During the early 1980s, it was the largest, and in
1991 the sixth-largest. It has since merged with the Banque de Indo
Suez. On December 2, 1945, the banking and credit industries were
nationalized, and the state became the sole shareholder of the Banque
de France and of the four principal deposit banks.
Reliance on the Bank of England was such that when its
charter was
renewed in 1781, it was described as "the public exchequer". By then,
the Bank was acting also as the bankers' bank and it had to keep enough
gold reserves to pay its notes on demand.
By 1797, war with France under Napoleon I had drained British
gold
reserves and the British government prohibited the Bank from paying its
notes in gold. This Restriction Period lasted until 1821. The 1844 Bank
Charter Act again tied the note issue to the Bank's gold reserves,
requiring the Bank to keep the accounts of the note issue separate from
those of its banking operations and produce a weekly summary of both
accounts, called the Bank Return, which is still published weekly
today. The Bank's second century thus saw two key elements of central
banking emerge: 1) the concern for monetary stability, born during the
inflationary excesses of the Napoleonic Wars; and 2) the institutional
responsibility for financial stability, developed in the banking crises
of the mid-19th century. Both elements were predicated on the
controversial assumption that long term financial-stability rests on
price stability, preventing the fluctuation of prices from being a tool
for managing the economy.
In the 19th century, the Bank of England took on the
additional role of
lender of last resort, providing stability to the banking system during
several financial crises. In the early 1900s, the Bank of England
became the instrument of the ruling class as distinguished from the
nation. It could and did lower prices and wages, increase unemployment
and even set the price of gold to protect private wealth gained from
the nation's global empire, which was unequally shared among its
citizens, let alone colonial subjects, in the name of capital
formation.
During World War I, the national debt jumped to STG7 billion.
The Bank
helped manage government borrowing and resist inflationary pressures.
As with the wars with France a century before, the financial cost of
World War I forced a break in the British currency link with gold. An
attempt was made in 1925 in vain to return to the gold standard, and in
1931, in the midst of worldwide depression, the United Kingdom left the
gold standard for good. Britain's gold and foreign-exchange reserves
were transferred to the Treasury, while their day-to-day management was
and still is handled by the Bank. The note issue became entirely
fiduciary, not backed by gold. Since then, the pound sterling has been
a fiat currency.
After World War II, the Bank of England was nationalized in
1946 under
a Labour government with the passing of the Bank of England Act, which
shifted authority on monetary policy to the British Treasury. The Bank
then acted as the government's bank, providing loans through ways and
means advances and arranging sovereign borrowing through the issue of
gilt-edged securities. The Bank helped to implement the government's
financial and monetary policy as directed by the Treasury. It also was
granted wide statutory powers to supervise the banking system,
including the commercial banks to which, through the discount market,
it acted as lender of last resort. The Bank remained the Treasury's
adviser, agent and debt manager. During and for years after the war, it
administered exchange control and various borrowing restrictions on the
Treasury's behalf.
The anti-depression cheap-money policies in the 1930s
persisted in
Britain after World War II, and during the 1960s, British monetary
policy came under the influence of the Radcliffe Report, released in
1959, which concluded that monetary policy should give priority to
controlling the liquidity of the monetary system, and not the quantity
of money in the system. The report did not dismiss the importance of
the quantity of money, but rather believed that given proper control of
liquidity, the quantity of money would self adjust. In external policy,
the report was supportive of fixed exchange rates as set up in the
Bretton Woods regime of exchange controls, which alleviated the
inherent contradiction between fixed exchange rates with full
convertibility and domestic monetary-policy flexibility. The Bretton
Woods regime did not consider free international movement of capital
necessary or desirable and was aware of the incompatibility of fixed
exchange rates and the lifting of exchange control.
As the apparatus of postwar controls gradually lifted in
Britain, the
need for a proactive monetary policy became more apparent, and the high
inflation of the 1970s and early 1980s provided the catalyst for policy
change. Monetary targets were introduced in 1976, and reinforced in the
early 1980s. These proved unreliable as a sole guide to policy;
nevertheless a monetarist consensus emerged: that price stability was
deemed desirable in its own right and a necessary condition of
sustainable growth. Inflation was singled out as the sole cause for
stagnant growth and other social costs.
Milton Friedman asserted that inflation is everywhere a
monetary
phenomenon; and without appropriate monetary measures, inflation could
not be properly brought under control. Inflation was seen as not merely
being destructive of wealth, but also as causing unemployment in the
long run. Thus a theoretical justification was found to fight inflation
with unemployment. Lay off workers now before inflation does it for you
later, economists would tell management. The outcome of this approach
was a new phenomenon known as stagflation, in which inflation and
unemployment rose together, as producers raised prices to compensate
for falling revenue from declining sales volume, diluting the
purchasing power of money, at the same time laying off workers to cut
costs to compensate for a declining profit margin. Unemployment then
led to reduced consumer spending, forcing companies to lay off more
workers and raise prices to compensate for lost sales in a downward
spiral.
During the 1970s, the Bank of England played a key role
during several
banking crises of stagflation in Britain and again in the 1980s when
monetary policy again became a central part of British government
policy. The Bank of England did not become a central bank until May
1997 when the government gave the Bank responsibility for setting
interest rates to meet the government's stated inflation target, a good
decade after the Big Bang. That was the term given to the financial
deregulation on October 27, 1989, of the London-based security market.
The Big Bang was comparable to May Day in 1975 in the United States,
which ushered in an era of discount brokerage and diversification into
a wide range of financial services using computer technology and
advanced communication systems, marking a major step toward a single
world financial market.
The Exchange Rate Mechanism (ERM) was a fixed-exchange-rate
regime
established by the then European Community designed to keep the member
countries' exchange rates within specific bands in relation to one
another. The purpose of the ERM was to stabilize exchange rates,
control inflation rates (through the link with the strong and stable
deutschmark) and nurture intra-Europe trade. It was also designed to
enhance European world trade in competition with the US, creating a
so-called "United States of Europe" and as a stepping stone to a
single-currency regime - the euro.
Britain joined the ERM in October 1990 at a fixed central
parity of
2.95 deutschmarks to the pound, an over-valued rate intended to put
pressure upon the British economy to reduce inflation rather than
institutionalizing international competitiveness. British pride might
have played a role in insisting on a strong pound. This chosen rate, or
any fixed rate required by ERM membership, proved misguided, because it
tried to benefit from the effect of a single currency for separate
economies without the reality of a single currency within an integrated
economy.
During the 23 months of ERM membership, from October 1990 to
September
1992, Britain suffered its worst recession in six decades, with the
gross domestic product (GDP) shrinking by 3.86 percent, unemployment
rose by 1.2 million to 2.85 million. The total price of ERM fixed
exchange rate for the United Kingdom had been estimated to be as high
as 13.3 percent of 1992 GDP. The number of residential mortgages with
negative equity tripled, reaching a peak of 1.25 million, and company
insolvency rose above 25,000 a year.
The British government of John Major sought to balance
political and
macroeconomic considerations, only to fail in its effort to "support
the unsupportable" to prevent a devaluation of a freely traded pound by
market forces. If the UK had not lost some STG8.2 billion defending the
pound's unsustainable exchange rate, it could have avoided budget
deficits, tax hikes, cuts in public spending, and the unpopular
value-added tax on fuel. Spending on the National Health Service could
have been more than doubled for 12 months.
Withdrawing from the ERM released the UK economy from
persistent
deflation and provided the foundation for the non-inflationary growth
subsequently experienced. It enabled monetary policy to be freed from
the sole task of maintaining the exchange rate, thus contributing to
economic expansion by a combination of rational monetary measures.
While ERM countries were compelled to maintain relatively high real
interest rates to prevent their currencies from falling outside the
permitted bands, Britain enjoyed the freedom to benefit from lower
rates. Hong Kong has been facing the same problems in the past five
years and will not recover from economic crisis until its currency peg
to the US dollar is lifted. Waiting for an improved economy before
depegging is like waiting for death to cure an infection.
The appropriate exchange rate of currencies at any particular
time is
that which enables their economies to combine full employment of
productive resources, including labor, with a simultaneous
balance-of-payment equilibrium. An excessively high exchange rate
causes trade deficits and domestic unemployment, while a low one
generates an excessive buildup of foreign-currency reserves and
stimulates domestic inflationary pressures that lead to a bubble
economy. Thus every nation must retain the ability to adjust the
external values of its currency in this unregulated global financial
market and an international financial architecture based on dollar
hegemony. To be fixated on a fixed exchange rate within rigid limits is
to court economic disaster in the current international finance
architecture.
The ERM was a transitional regime whose problems were finally
removed
once the EU moved toward a single currency in the form of the euro.
Still, the anti-inflation bias of the European Central Bank continues
to create conflict with monetary policy needs of national economies
within euroland.
In a fast-changing economic environment of unregulated
globalized
markets, the value of the exchange rate that facilitates full
employment and a foreign trade balance will frequently fluctuate.
Speculative volatility must be countered and the exchange rate managed
by the national bank to prevent disruption in the domestic economy and
in external trade. However, this does not imply fixed, unchangeable
bands as under the ERM. The optimum strategy for cooperation between
national central banks on exchange rates requires a combination of
maximum short-term stability with maximum long-term flexibility, the
opposite of the effects of fixed exchange rates.
Since, under ERM, Britain's interest rate was pegged to that
of Germany
through the fixed exchange rate, reduction in interest rates was not
available to deal with increasing unemployment and declining growth in
the UK. The fact that Britain had no control over interest rates,
coupled with the questionable independence of the Bundesbank, Germany's
central bank, was an important factor in the final decision to withdraw
the pound from the ERM fixed-exchange-rate regime.
The reunification of Germany cracked open the structural flaw
in the
Exchange Rate Mechanism because massive capital injection from West to
East Germany had produced inflationary pressure in the newly unified in
German economy, leading to preemptive increases of interest rates by
the Bundesbank. At the same time other economies in Europe, especially
that of Britain, were in recession and not prepared for interest-rate
hikes dictated by Germany. This interest-rate disparity magnified the
overvaluation of the pound in the early 1990s.
Along with the European Currency Unit (ECU, the forerunner of
the
euro), the ERM was one of the foundation stones of economic and
monetary union in Europe. It gave currencies a central exchange rate
against the ECU, which in turn gave them central cross-rates against
one another. It was hoped that the mechanism would help stabilize
exchange rates, encourage trade within Europe and control inflation.
The ERM gave national currencies an upper and lower limit on either
side of this central rate within which they could fluctuate.
In 1992, the ERM was torn apart when a number of currencies
could not
keep within these limits without collapsing their economies. On
Wednesday, September 16, a culmination of factors led Britain to pull
out of the ERM and to let the pound float according to market forces.
Black Wednesday became the day on which George Soros, hedge-fund titan,
broke the Bank of England, pocketing US$1 billion of profit in one day
and more than $2 billion eventually. The British pound was forced to
leave the ERM after the Bank of England spent $40 billion in an
unsuccessful effort to defend the currency's fixed value against
speculative attack. The Italian lira also left and the Spanish peseta
was devaluated.
In order to curb German inflation, an increase in German
interest rates
was necessary, but if the Bundesbank were completely independent of
German political-economic interests as a dominant regional central
bank, it would not have adopted this policy, as there were cries from
all over Europe for a decrease in interest rates. By adopting tight
monetary policies in response to domestic inflationary pressures that
followed German reunification in 1990, German short-term interest
rates, which had been rising since 1988, continued to rise, reaching
nearly 10 percent by the summer of 1992. So, at a time when Britain
needed a counter-cyclical reduction in interest rates, the Bundesbank
sent the interest rate upwards, plunging Britain deeper into recession
through the ERM.
This was the fundamental problem with the ERM - fixed
exchange rates
conflicted with the interest-rate levels needed by different economic
conditions in separate member economies. The British interest rate
pegged to that set by the Bundesbank was crippling the British economy
because the UK was in a recession and required low interest rates.
In 1997, the British government announced its intention to
transfer
full operational responsibility for monetary policy to the Bank of
England. The Bank thus joined the ranks of the world's "independent"
central banks. However, debt management on behalf of the government was
transferred to Her Majesty's Treasury, and the Bank's regulatory
functions passed to the new Financial Services Authority.
Germany has a vital banking tradition that dates back to the
great
Fugger money-lending network in the 15th and 16th centuries, and before
that the limited banking practices required by the Hanseatic League
(Hansa) of northern Germany in the 14th century. Germany's first
commercial bank was established in Hamburg in 1619. The Giro bank
lasted until its takeover by the state-run Reichsbank in 1875.
By the early 1800s Frankfurt am Main was a banking center
under the
House of Rothschild. The Rothschilds, in fact, took their name from the
red (roth) shield (Schild) on the front of their
Frankfurt home during the first years of the Jewish family's history.
Their banking dynasty soon extended beyond Frankfurt to London, Naples,
Paris, and Vienna.
On January 18, 1871, Otto von Bismarck proclaimed in
Versailles the
German Empire. Between 1870 and 1872 several other important German
banks evolved, some of which are still around in one form or another,
despite political interruptions associated with Germany being the
vanquished in two world wars.
Until the 1870s, the financial regulation of German overseas
trade had
been almost exclusively in the hands of London banks. The historical
structure of independent principalities under the Holy Roman Empire
presented an obstacle to German unification and by implication the
emergence of a German national bank. The establishment in 1870 of the
Deutsche Bank at Berlin was a turning point. The Deutsche Bank's
charter identified the purpose of the corporation as "to do a general
banking business, particularly to further and facilitate commercial
relations between Germany, the other European countries, and oversea
markets".
The founders of the Deutsche Bank had recognized that there
existed in
the organization of the German banking and credit system a gap that had
to be filled in order to render German foreign trade independent of the
English intermediary, and to secure for German commerce a firm position
in the international market. It was rather difficult to carry out this
program during the early years because Germany at that time had no gold
standard and bills of exchange made out in various kinds of Germanic
currency were neither known nor liked in the international market. The
introduction of the gold standard in Germany in 1873 did away with
these difficulties, and by establishing branches at the central points
of German overseas trade (Bremen and Hamburg) and by opening an agency
in London, the Deutsche Bank succeeded in vigorously furthering its
nationalist program.
Later the other Berlin joint-stock banks, especially the
Disconto
Gesellschaft and the Dresdner Bank, followed the example of the
Deutsche Bank, and during the past decade particularly the Berlin
joint-stock banks have shown great energy in extending the sphere of
their interests abroad. The German banks suffered the largest loss in
the 1997 financial crisis in Asia, partly because, being latecomers,
they fell victim the classical buy-high-sell-low syndrome.
The central bank of Germany is the Deutsche Bundesbank, with
its head
office in Frankfurt. It is a federal corporation under public law, and
also performs supervisory functions in the same way as the Federal
Banking Supervisory Office. Its powers of authority are governed by a
special law, the Bundesbank Act. Until December 31, 1998, the
Bundesbank had the exclusive right to issue banknotes and coins and had
been assigned the task of maintaining the stability of the national
currency by regulating the money supply and the amount of credit
available to the economy. This exclusive right was transferred to the
European Central Bank on January 1, 1999, with the start of the common
currency, the euro.
After the adoption last April 22 of the Law on Integrated
Financial
Services Supervision (Gesetz uber die integrierte Finanzaufsicht -
FinDAG), the German Financial Supervisory Authority (Bundesanstalt fur
Finanzdienstleistungsaufsicht -BAFin) was established on May 1. The
functions of the former offices for banking supervision
(Bundesaufsichtsamt fur das Kreditwesen - BAKred), insurance
supervision (Bundesaufsichtsamt fur das Versicherungswesen - BAV) and
securities supervision (Bundesaufsichtsamt fur den Wertpapierhandel -
BAWe) have been combined in a single state regulator that supervises
banks, financial services institutions and insurance undertakings
across the entire financial market and comprises all the key functions
of consumer protection and solvency supervision. The new German
Financial Supervisory Authority is intended to make a valuable
contribution to the stability of Germany as a financial center and
improve its competitiveness.
The BAFin is a federal institution governed by public law
that belongs
to the portfolio of the Federal Ministry of Finance and, as such, has a
legal personality. Its two offices are in Bonn and Frankfurt/Main. The
BAFin supervises about 2,700 banks, 800 financial services institutions
and more than 700 insurance undertakings.
The Deutsche Bundesbank, the central bank of the Federal
Republic of
Germany, is an integral part of the European System of Central Banks
(ESCB). The Bundesbank participates in the fulfillment of the ESCB's
tasks with the primary objective of maintaining the stability of the
euro, and it ensures the orderly execution of domestic and foreign
payments. It was established in 1957 as the sole successor to the
two-tier central bank system that comprised the Bank Deutscher Lander
and the Land Central Banks. At the time, the Land Central Banks were
legally independent bodies. Together, the institutions in the central
bank system bore responsibility for the German currency from June 20,
1948, when the deutschmark was introduced, until the Deutsche
Bundesbank was founded.
As a result of the Bundesbank's becoming part of the European
System of
Central Banks (ESCB), the need to restructure became increasingly
evident. The Bundesbank's organizational structure has now been changed
by means of the Seventh Act Amending the Bundesbank Act, which came
into effect on April 30. The Bundesbank's decision-making body, the
executive board, normally convenes in Frankfurt. It comprises the
president, the vice president and six other members. Its mandate is to
govern and manage the Bundesbank.
The board will draw up an organizational statute to establish
how
responsibilities are shared out among the board members and to
determine the tasks that may be delegated to the regional offices. The
members of the board are all appointed by the president of the federal
republic. The president, the vice president and two other members are
nominated by the German federal government, while the other four
members are nominated by the Bundesrat in agreement with the federal
government.
Until recently, the five largest German banks are Deutsche
Bank,
Dresdner Bank, Westdeutsche Landesbank, Commerzbank and the Bayerische
Vereinsbank. In 1994 Frankfurt won the heated contest to house the
European Monetary Institute (EMI), the precursor to the current
European Central Bank (ECB), which began operations in Frankfurt in
January 1999 with the introduction of the euro. Until the ECB began
operation in 1999, Germany's Bundesbank, known as the Buba to the
financially literate, was Europe's most influential central bank. For
all practical purposes, the Bundesbank was to Europe what the US
Federal Reserve Bank is to the United States; indeed, the Fed served as
a model for the postwar German central bank.
A proposed Deutsche and Dresdner merger would have changed
the playing
field not just in Germany but also throughout Europe. The merger
proposal was driven by two factors. First, banks fear e-commerce will
cut into already dwindling retail profits. Second, the two banks want
to get bigger so they can compete with US banks globally in the more
profitable investment banking market. The bank merger proposal followed
the takeover of Mannesmann by Vodafone - the first hostile takeover in
Germany - and such deals signal the changing face of German corporate
culture. The collapse of the Internet and telecom bubbles has cast
doubt on the validity of these mergers.
Germany's complex systems of cross-shareholdings between
major
companies appears to be unraveling, increasing the chance that some of
it could fall into foreign hands. The move marks a shift from retail
banking, which has proved to be an unprofitable headache for many
German banks. Deutsche Bank had planned to invest up to 1 billion euros
every year in Internet ventures before the bubble burst. In 1998,
Deutsche Bank bought Bankers Trust of the United States for $10
billion, with highly mixed results to date.
Before the stewardship of Paul Volcker, since the New Deal
after the
1930 Great Depression, the historic bias in the US Federal Reserve
Board had given a higher priority to jobs and growth than to price
stability. The ECB, which has inherited the German obsession with
inflation born out of the country's hyperinflation experience of the
past century, is still fixated on its anti-inflation bias. Most
neo-liberal economists identify Germany, the growth engine of euroland,
as the root cause of the eurozone's weakness, saddled with three
interlinked problems of inflationary pressures from unification, an
uncompetitive conversion exchange rate with the euro, and a policy
inertia against structural reforms. Yet neo-liberal reform requires the
wholesale abandonment of the historical and cultural essence of German
economic structure.
The ECB is working at cross purposes against its member
governments,
which need relief from its strict deficit rules in economic downturns.
The ECB's determination to demonstrate its independence from eurozone
political reality is preventing it from being a constructive force in
economic recovery.
The classic error of central banks doing too little too late
now
infects all three key central banks in the West: the Fed, the ECB, and
the Bank of England.
Next: The US
Experience
|