Wages of Neoliberalsim
Part I: Core Contrdictions
By
Henry C.K. Liu
First appeared in Asia Times
March 22, 2006
US
trade deficit with China ballooned in 2005 to $202 billion, more than
one-quarter of the total US deficit. Rising trade imbalance between the
US and
China in recent years has given rise to intense pressure from the US on
China
to revalue the fixed exchange rate of its currency that had been pegged
at 8.28
yuan to a dollar within a narrow band of 0.03% for a decade from
1995-2005. On
July 21, 2005, after repeated pronouncements that no revaluation was
necessary
or even being considered, China announced a surprised 2% appreciation
of the
Chinese currency, making it at 8.11 yuan to the US dollar. It also
announced
that the RMB yuan will henceforth be pegged with the same narrow range
to a
basket of foreign currencies that includes dollars, euro, yen and
others likely
to reflect China's trade relationships with the
rest of the world. The components and weight of different currencies
within the
basket is not disclosed to the market. China appears to be following
the
Singapore managed float model, keeping both weights and effective bands
confidential to allow maximum flexibility within a narrow range tied to
a
reference peg to the dollar. Many saw it
as obviously a political move to appease US pressure.
Yet US pressure on China to further revalue the yuan
continues as the trade deficit with China for January 2006 registered
$17.9
billion, a 10% increase from the previous month. Total worldwide US
trade
deficit for the month was $68.5 billion despite a rise in US exports in
airplanes and soybeans. This pressure from
the US is motivated by the misguided
conventional assumption that a lower exchange rate of the dollar will
reduce
the
US trade deficit,
despite clear
historical data showing that past revaluations of the Japanese yen and
the
German mark had not reduced US trade deficits with these major trade
partners in
the long run. All such revaluations did
was to lower the domestic cost in local currency terms more than raise
the dollar
price of Japanese and German exports.
The net effect was deflation in Japan and Germany, with inflation in
the
US while the US trade deficit continued.
The
dollar takes the form of a US Federal Reserve note, a monetary
instrument
issued by a central bank. The yuan takes the form of a Chinese People’s
Currency (Renminbi, or RMB) issued by the People’s Bank of China
(PBoC), another
central bank. Both are fiat currencies issued by central banks in that
they are
money with no intrinsic value, not backed by gold or other species of
value. Both currencies are not issued directly by
their respective governments, but by their respective central
banks. This means that the full faith and credit of
the nation is not directly behind either of these currencies. A holder
of these
fiat currencies cannot go to their governments to claim a piece of the
national
wealth. The values of either of these currencies are determined by
their
purchasing powers in the respective economies as affected by the
monetary
policies of their respective issuers, i.e. the respective central
banks. The
holder of a dollar is entitled to exchange it at the Fed for another
dollar, no
more, no less. The dollar’s purchasing power within the US is affected
by the
Fed’s monetary policy as such policy affects the inflation or deflation
rates
in the US economy. The same is true for
the RMB. Thus the exchange rate of the
two currencies reflects the domestic purchasing power differential
caused by
the monetary polices of their respective central banks which are in
principle
politically independent.
The
trade imbalance between the US and China is not caused by the exchange
rate of
the two currencies. It is caused mainly by a disparity in the factors
of
production, such as wages and rent as expressed in prices in the two
trading economies. Chinese trade imbalance with the US is
primarily caused by Chinese wages and rent being too low compared to
equivalent
productivity in US wages and rent. The dys-functionality in the
exchange rate between
the yuan and the dollar is the result, not the cause of the trade
imbalance. To
correct this trade imbalance, Chinese wages and rent need to rise, not
the
Chinese currency. Wages and rent in the two trading economies need to
converge
toward parity, rather than the currencies to diverge from any
particular
exchange rate that has been in operation for a decade. The yuan
at 8.12 to one dollar is already
valued at twice the purchasing power parity gap of 4 between it and the
dollar
within their respective economies. Wage disparity between China and the
US
ranges from 20 to 50 times in various sectors and an exchange rate that
reflects such wide disparity would border on the ridiculous. According
to estimates in the World Bank's 2002 World Development Report,
which is most often quoted when discussing purchasing power parity
(PPP), prices in China were only 21% of those in the US when converted
using the then exchange rate of 8.28 yuan to the dollar. To
equalize the price levels between China and the US, the yuan must
appreciate to 1.74 to the dollar (8.28 x 0.21). In other words, if
prices in the US are the standard, PPP holds when the yuan is at 1.74
to the dollar - 4.7 times the actual exchange rate.
The lower the income levels in a developing
country, the lower the exchange rate of its currency compared to its
PPP. China is no exception. This reflects the "Balassa-Samuelson
effect," which states that even if the law of one price generally
applies to tradable goods such as industrial products, most services,
which are non-tradable goods, are cheaper in low-income countries as
they reflect differences in wage levels. This observation indicates
that the disparity between a currency's exchange rate and its
theoretical PPP will narrow as that country's economy develops, and
when it approaches the level of industrialized nations, its exchange
rate converges to a level that generally matches its PPP. Thus the
exchange rate of the yuan should be adjusted upward only as Chinese
wages rise.
A
stable exchange rate is not only beneficial to trade, but it is also
fundamentally
critical to global financial stability. Every
financial crisis sine the 1971 collapse of the Bretton Woods fixed
exchange
rate regime has been caused by exchange rate instability. Exchange rate
policies
cannot be substitutes for structural economic adjustments necessary for
mutually beneficial trade between two economies. Nor can exchange rate
policies
be substitutes for sound domestic monetary or economic policy.
When two economies of uneven stages of
development trade, a trade surplus in favor of the less-developed
economy is
natural and just, until the less-developed economy catches up with the
more-developed
one, otherwise it would be imperialistic exploitation, not trade.
Market forces
on exchange rates are derived from the relative strength of trading
economies. Foreign
exchange markets express the net summary judgments of market
participants on
the economic health of trading economies as they are affected by
government
fiscal and central bank monetary policies. Markets use exchange rate
fluctuation to carry the message of aggregate judgments to the monetary
and
fiscal authorities of the trading economies. These authorities,
usually the Central Bank
and the Treasury, cannot ignore such market sentiments without a
cost. For economies where the currencies are freely
convertible, the cost can be massive attacks on their currencies by
speculators, such as hedge funds, that would quickly drain the
government’s
foreign exchange reserves and cause a collapse in the economy’s debt
market.
For economies that practice exchange and capital control, the penalty
would be a
drain in foreign reserves and a reduction in trade in the case of a
deficit. In
the case of a trade surplus, the penalty would be a drain of domestic
currency capital
into growing foreign exchange reserves.
In the current
global central banking regime, fiat
currencies are issued mostly directly by central banks or by banks
authorized
by the central bank to issue currency, such as in former British
colonies like
Hong Kong. Central banks are supposed to be politically independent in
its key
role of maintaining the stability and the value of a nation’s fiat
money,
unaffected by constant and relentless political pressure for easy
money. The value of the fiat currency of a sovereign
nation is backed only by the nation’s economic health and by the
issuing
government’s acceptance of it for payment of taxes. It enjoys
monopoly status as legal tender for
settlement of all debts within the country’s borders. Most
sovereign nations allow only their own
legal tenders to circulate within their borders and require that
foreign
currencies be first converted into local legal tenders before being
used in
domestic markets. For cross-border transactions, a foreign exchange
market is
necessary to interconvert legal tenders of trading nations at
economically
equitable rates.
When the foreign
exchange value of the fiat currency of a
country moves beyond what the government or the foreign exchange market
deems
appropriate, the correction needs to come from a readjustment of the
structure
of its economy, not from artificial manipulation of the exchange rate
of its
currency. Regardless if the exchange rate is fixed by government or by
market
forces, the volatility in the gap between the economic value of a fiat
currency
and its exchange rate is the main cause of financial instability.
Such instability has caused recurring
financial crises around the world in past decades since the collapse in
1971 of
the Bretton Woods regime of fixed exchange rates based on a gold-backed
dollar.
The
Conflicting Functions of Central Banks
The philosophical
underpin of a central banking regime is
the assumption that a stable value for a fiat currency is necessary for
the
long-term health of the economy. In a globalized market economy, the
domestic
purchasing power of a fiat currency in large measure affects its
exchange rate,
not the other way around. Yet most central banks, including the US Fed,
categorically defer exchange rate policy to the Treasury or Ministry of
Finance, on account that it is an issue of national economic security.
Further,
the reson
d’etre
for a central
banking regime is equally rooted in a contradicting assumption that
monetary
elasticity is necessary to respond to the changing financial needs of
the economy
in order to prevent cyclical bank crises and recessions or depressions.
Thus a
central bank’s first key function of preserving the domestic purchasing
power
of fiat money conflicts with its second key function of providing
monetary
elasticity to a slowing economy. A
central bank must restrain commercial banks from creating money through
excessive lending made possible by a partial reserve regulatory regime
while at
the same time it must act as a lender of last resort to lend when no
other
lender is willing or able to lend in an approaching financial crisis or
panic. The function of a lender of last resort is to
provide needed liquidity to a market in distress from already excessive
debt.
Without central bank liquidity reserve, a distressed market may freeze
in a
circular domino effect of even credit-worthy debtors being unable
temporarily
to meet their obligations because some less-credit-worthy debtors are
unable to
pay their debts to them. Such recurring
banking crisis had been regular in the US prior to the establishment of
the Federal
Reserve in 1913 and in recent decades in many other countries with
dollar debts
for which their central banks are unable to provide monetary elasticity
in
dollars because only the Fed can print dollars.
According to the
quantity theory of money, monetary
elasticity, when regularly invoked as convenient preventives against
cyclical slowdowns
in the economy, leads to a rise in “moral hazard” which is the
encouragement to
borrowers to take unwarranted financial risks with the knowledge that
such
risks would be protected by central bank bailouts. Monetary
elasticity is much easier to inject
than to retract because deflation is more painful than inflation for
debtors. Elasticity
loss is eventually caused by fatigue; the way rubber bands can get
stretched or
snapped. The Fed under Greenspan has repeatedly gone on record to
assert its belief
in the heresy that “highly aggressive monetary ease was doubtless also
a
significant contributor to stability.” Greenspan said in 2004 in
hindsight
after the bubble burst in 2000: “Instead of trying to contain a
putative bubble
by drastic actions with largely unpredictable consequences, we chose,
as we
noted in our mid-1999 congressional testimony, to focus on policies to
mitigate
the fallout when it occurs and, hopefully, ease the transition to the
next
expansion.” By “the next expansion”, Greenspan meant the next bubble,
which
manifested itself in housing after 2000. The “mitigating” response was
a
massive injection of liquidity into the US banking system.
There is a
structural reason why the housing bubble has replaced
the high-tech bubble. The US trade deficit finances the US capital
account
surplus which provides low-cost mortgages for the US housing market.
Houses
cannot be imported from low-wage countries like manufactured goods,
although
much of the contents in houses, such as furniture, hardware, windows,
kitchen
equipment, bath fixtures and heating and air-conditioning equipment are
manufactured overseas. Construction jobs cannot be outsourced overseas
to take
advantage of cross-border wage arbitrage, albeit many low-skill
construction
jobs are filled by illegal immigrants. But a housing bubble is not
different
than any other types of debt bubbles. It will burst if income fails to
grow
with asset value to sustain debt service payments.
Thus central banks
are saddled with conceptual contradictions
in assuming the dual role of a vigilant supervisor of the rules of
prudence in
the financial market at the same time acting as a permissive
cheerleader for
the infraction of the same rules in the name of innovative economic
expansion. Moreover, central bank criteria for bailouts of
distressed private firms are tied to their potential systemic impact.
Such
criteria are inherently undemocratic in that the large debtors
unfailingly get
preferred treatment merely because of their size. Hence the birth of a
rule of
finance that every borrower knows: if you owe the bank ten thousand
dollars, you
are beholden to the bank; but if you owe the bank ten billion dollars,
the bank
is beholden to you. It is known as the “too big to fail” syndrome. What
is even
more pathetic is that in the US, the Federal Reserve is legally owned
by its
member banks, not the government, or the people, albeit some 98% of the
profit
made by the Fed goes to the Treasury by law.
Board members of the Fed are nominated by the member banks and
appointed
by the President and as a group they predominantly represent the
special
interests of the banking sector.
In China, the
passage of the Central Bank Law in 1995
granted the People’s Bank of China central bank status, shifting it
away from
its previous role of a national bank. The difference between a national
bank and
a central bank is that a national bank serves the banking needs of the
economy
while a central bank seeks to maintain the stable value of the currency
and at
the same time to provide monetary elasticity to prevent banking crises,
and to
adopt an interest rate policy that ensures profitability to the banking
sector
with the idea that the banking sector, the heart of the economy must be
protected at all cost for the good of the economy. In the twilight zone
of Chinese
bank reform, no outsider knows how the process of nomination and
appointment of
the board members of the PBoC works. It is safe to say that the PBoC
still follows
the policy directives of the Chinese government which in turn follows
the policy
directive of the Communist Party of China (CPC). To the extend
that CPC policy drifts toward
market fundamentalism with Chinese characteristics, PBoC will
invariably also
drifts towards representing the special interests of the banking sector
and
their big business clients at the expense of the interests of the
proletariat
and peasant masses, or Chinese banks cannot profitably compete in the
world
market. Such is the class contradiction
of a “socialist market economy”, no matter how the term is defined with
doctrinal sophistry.
By the definition of
the Bank of International Settlement
(BIS), the super-national central bank for all national central banks,
such undemocratic
special interest posture is viewed as desirable “political
independence” in a capitalist
democratic society. Unlike the Fed which has an arms-length
relationship with
the US Treasury, the PBoC manages the State treasury as its fiscal
agent. In addition to regulating the inter-bank lending
market, the PBoC also regulates the inter-bank bond market, the foreign
exchange market and the gold market in China.
Political independence is not a policy subject Chinese central bankers
can
discuss with ease as long as China still views itself as a socialist
nation.
They prefer more benign euphemism in the jargons of bank reform such as
confirming to international standards. There are signs that after
almost three
decades of headlong reform toward what Chinese officials call socialist
market
economy, the adverse consequence are beginning to force recent Chinese
policy to shift
back toward populist directions to provide affirmative financial
assistance to
the poor and the undeveloped rural and interior regions and to reverse
blatant
income disparity and economic and regional imbalances. It can be
anticipated that this
policy shift will to raise questions in the capitalist West of the
political
independence of the PBoC. Western neo-liberals will be predictably
critical of
the PBoC for directing money to where the country needs it most, rather
than to
that part of the economy where bank profit would be highest.
The
Birth of the Bretton Woods Regime
After WWII, as the
US emerged as the only country the industrial
sector of which had been left not only undamaged but actually
strengthened by
war, the dollar by default became the uncontested world reserve
currency for
international trade. As early as April
1942, the so-called White plan, named after Harry Dexter White, US
Treasury
Undersecretary and a student of free trade advocate Professor Frank W.
Taussig
of Harvard, proposed a United Nations Stabilization Fund and a Bank for
Reconstruction and Development of the United and Associated Nations. The advantages of
stable exchange rates that the automatic classical gold standard had
provided
while it lasted, from 1876 to 1914, had proved to be not so automatic
after
WWI. Classical gold standard was causing deflation around that world
that
translated into a worldwide depression while mercantilism, the quest by
nations
for gold through exporting, was causing protectionist reaction in all
countries.
The idea of the need
for international cooperation in trade and
for a new “gold exchange standard” which would make wider use of gold
by
supplementing it with an anchor currency that would be readily
convertible into
gold had been developed in the 1920 international conference in Genoa,
Italy,
but the participating governments failed to reach agreement on account
not all
were ready to accept British sterling hegemony. This idea was
incorporated two
and a half decades later into the Bretton Woods regime with a
gold-backed
dollar replacing the British pound. The challenge was to devise an
operative international
finance architecture out of fiat currencies anchored to a gold-backed
dollar to
accommodate post-war international trade.
On August 14, 1941,
some fours months before Japanese attacks
on Pearl Harbor, the US, not yet at war, issued jointly with a Britain
already at
war with Germany, the Atlantic Charter which set out a post-war world
vision as
unspoken condition for pending US alliance with Britain. Among
other provisions, the Atlantic Charter
emphasized British commitment to postwar international cooperation,
including support
for US efforts to form a United Nations based on the principle of
self-determination for former colonies. Six months later, in February
1942, barely
two months after Pearl Harbor, under the Lend-Lease agreement, Britain
agreed
to a postwar multilateral payments system in exchange for US commitment
to help
Britain financially during and after the war.
Four months after
the declaration of the Atlantic Charter, on
Sunday, December l4, 1941, one week after Pearl Harbor, while the US
was
mobilizing for all-out war, Treasury Secretary Henry Morgenthau was
busy figuring
out how to finance the war. He asked
White to prepare a monetary stabilization plan that would include all
the
Allies while Britain was also busy preparing its own plan. One crucial
difference between
the US plan by White and the British plan by John Maynard Keynes was
that the
Stabilization Fund (SF) proposed by the US was to be based on a mixed
bag of
national currencies, while the Clearing Union (CU) proposed by Britain
was to
operate with a new international currency to be known as bancor. The CU also had
less strict rules than did the (SF) for its
use by countries with balance-of-payments deficits. The US was
concerned about the potential
financial liability of the US and about the rights of creditor
countries with
balance-of-payments surpluses, which at that time meant only the US.
The US team
voiced serious reservations about the British/Keynes plan, which had
liberal
liquidity provisions and ready access to liquidity for countries with
temporary
trade deficits. Britain anticipated huge
war-time deficits as revenue from many parts of the British Empire was
suddenly
interrupted.
The IMF closely
followed the US/White plan for a contributory fund, although it
was slightly larger,
at $8.8 billion ($77 billion in 2004 dollar or $463 in
relative
share of GDP), of which the USA put in $2.75 billion ($24 billion in
2004
dollar or $145 in relative share of GDP), and the UK
contributed
$1.3 billion. Exchange rates could fluctuate 1 per cent on either side
of a par value with the dollar. The fund was designed to provide
members with a cushion of credit to give them the confidence to abandon
exchange and trade controls while keeping their exchange rate stable in
terms of US dollars. It did
not deal with how the transition from war through reconstruction to
recovery was to be achieved. The IMF was specifically not to lend for
relief or reconstruction arising from the war. Article XIV allowed
members to keep exchange controls for three to five years, after which
they had to report annually on why controls still remained. This left
open the absolute deadline for abandoning exchange controls or trade
restrictions, and in the event they were not abandoned for current
account purposes until 1958. The UK only abandoned its final controls
on capital flows in 1979.
In addition, the
US/White plan contemplated the forbiddance of
exchange rate intervention, an important feature for the US, whereas
the British/Keynes
plan did not put much emphasis on limits on exchange rate intervention
and even
advocated the use of capital controls for the weaker economies, of
which
Britain expected to become one in the course of the war. Britain
imposed
exchange control soon after the war began and kept it for four decades
until
the new Conservative government abolished exchange control in
1979. The pre-1979 controls on direct investment
restricted sterling-financed foreign investment except where it had a
positive
effect on the balance of payments. With respect to portfolio
investment, the
controls stipulated that purchase by UK residents of foreign exchange
to invest
overseas could be made only from the sale of existing foreign
securities or
from foreign currency borrowing. A third
element of the controls restricted the holding by UK residents of
foreign
currency deposits as well as sterling lending to overseas residents.
The 1944-5
international conference at Bretton Woods, New
Hampshire was attended by representatives of 44 governments who agreed
on “a
framework for economic cooperation partly designed to avoid a
repetition of the
disastrous economic policies that had contributed to the Great
Depression of
the 1930s” that led to a further eclipse of a British Empire already
weakened
by World War I. British resistance, with
US support, to geopolitical challenge to her crumbling empire from
rising
powers such as Japan and Germany in the 1930s eventually led to World
War II
which was a geopolitical contest between competing powers that morphed
into an
ideological contest between democracy and fascism, an image created by
Anglo-US
propaganda as a high-principle pretext to marshal domestic political
support
for war. While constantly vowing in private that Britain did not go to
war
merely to give the empire away, Churchill cleverly referred to the
Allies in
public as the democracies to appease historical US anti-colonial
ideology. Churchill neutralized the isolationist elite
in the US by appealing to the anti-communist right in US politics with
conservative
rhetoric in his spirited speeches. Taking advantage of a common
language,
Churchill’s ringing speeches sounded inspiring to the US public just as
Hitler’s firebrand speeches inspired the Austrians. In fact, the
phrase “Iron Curtain” in
Churchill’s heroic March 5, 1946 speech in Fulton, Missouri, Truman’s
home
state, that launched the Cold War, was stolen from Nazi propaganda
chief Joseph
Geobbl.
Churchill’s
protective posture towards fascist Spain
illustrates his ambivalence towards fascism. On June 19, 1945, at the
San
Francisco Conference, the United Nations, reincarnation of the Allied
Powers,
voted unanimously to exclude Franco’s fascist Spain. Then, at the
Potsdam
Conference later that same summer, Stalin proposed the Allies break
diplomatic
relations with fascist Spain, a worldwide total boycott, and that the
Allies
should aid the “democratic opposition” within Spain. Truman was in
favor, which
was the only time he and Stalin ever agreed to anything, but Churchill
opposed the
idea by pointing out that Britain had strong trade links with Spain
that a
post-war Britain could not afford to break and that “interference in
the
internal affairs of other states was contrary to the United Nations
Charter.”
Churchill was counting on the Spanish fascists to keep the Spanish
communists
from gaining back Spain lost in the Civil War through Third Reich help
to
Franco. So much for
the wsr to make the world safe for democracy.
The USSR, while
wanting to appear to be associated with plans
being fashioned at Bretton Woods out of a desire to be perceived as a
participating world power, showed little enthusiasm for monetary
cooperation
with US capitalism. Soviet economists were not interested in capitalist
world
trade and they lacked sufficient theoretical sophistication to
understand the
subtleties between the contested proposals in capitalist economies. The
USSR
agreed to send a technical observer delegation to the Bretton Woods
conference without
the commissar of finance. Britain, concerned with preserving its
special economic
relationship with members of the British Commonwealth, reorganized from
a
collapsed empire, also said it would not send cabinet-level officials
to the
conference. Both Britain and the USSR asserted that participation in
the
conference in no way foreclosed their option to reject eventual
membership in
the proposed International Monetary Fund.
The Bretton Woods
conference, predominantly a US-run show, produced
an international financial regime that set
the value of the dollar at 1/35th of an ounce of gold
with all other
currencies of other participating nations set at fixed exchange rates
to the
dollar that were not expected to fluctuate beyond a narrow range of 1%
from unruly
market forces. Foreign exchange control between borders was strictly
enforced. Official
exchange rates were determined by economic fundamentals and were
expected to
change only fundamentally, but not temporarily due to speculative
forces,
because trade was supposed to increase wealth for all trading nations
proportionately and not expected to alter their relative wealth.
Cross-border
flows of funds were not considered by then prevalent trade economics
theories
as either necessary for trade or desirable for domestic
development. All members of the United Nations were
eligible to join, provided they were committed both to eliminating
controls
over foreign exchange transactions and to establishing fixed exchange
rates, to
be altered only with the consent of the Fund. Trade, though not
unimportant,
was considered as having only a supplementary function in a nation’s
economy,
the main economic functions being in the domestic economic
development. A weak domestic economy could not possibly be
expected to solve its problems through trade alone. National economic
development was the goal of every nation, with trade being conducted
only for
auxiliary purposes. This
was just common
sense, for no nation would tolerate or could afford a sustained trade
deficit.
Trade between nations either had to be balanced or trade would soon
stop until
temporary trade deficits were eliminated. No country would be foolish
enough to exort real goods for another country's fiat paper only to
lend it back to the deficit trader to incur a larger trade deficit, at
least not until the US devise dollar hegemony after it abondoned the
Bretton Woods regime in 1971. If every national economy were to
seek
growth only through exports, the aggregate effect for the world economy
would
be negative, which was exactly what happened since the end of the Cold
War.
While World War II was a global conflict
between the Allies and the Axis powers, a parallel undercurrent
financial war
was waged between the two leading allies.
British historian Robert Skidelsky in his
three-volume biography of John
Maynard Keynes writes (p. 239) of
the relationship between Keynes who represented Britain and White who
represented the US at Bretton Woods as a “battle between the two... one
of the
grand political duels of the Second World War, though it was largely
buried in
financial minutiae...” He sees the differences as the result of US
malevolence
(p. xx): “Harry Dexter White of the US
Treasury wanted to cripple Britain in order to clear the ground for a
post-war
American-Soviet alliance...” Later in
the McCarthy era, White was accused unfairly of having been a
communist, on
flimsy circumstantial evidence, notwithstanding that in the 1920s,
every
thinking individual in the US cultural scene was to some degree
sympathetic to
communism. Critics on the right in the US at the time saw Bretton Woods
as an attempt
to “set up a super-national Brains Trust which is to think for the
world and
plan for the world, and to tell the governments of the world what to
do.”
The
Financial War between Allies
After Dunkirk when
the badly mauled British military retrieved
its expeditionary force of 300,000 by the skin of their teeth with the
use of civilian
small boats, the British had to make a choice: either to lose the
military war
to Germany as France did, or to lose the financial war to the US.
Churchill chose losing to the US, based on
the time-honored strategic theory of keeping distant allies to oppose
nearby enemies. Churchill was out and out pro-US, with his
American mother, and close connection to the US moneyed elite.
This policy was not unanimously supported by
all in Britain, the Duke of Windsor being a prominent example.
Churchill’s choice turned out to be the only
sensible option, with Canada dominated by the US and Hong Kong,
Singapore, Malaysia,
British Broneo, India and Australia threatened by a hostile Japan, an
ally of
Germany. Moving General Douglas MacArthur
from embarrassing defeat by the Japanese in the Philippines to
Australia
cemented British-US interests in Asia and saved the US from an
unthinkable
disgrace of having a top general surrender to what was commonly
considered by
US sentiment as an inferior race. Since 1941, Britain has been holding
up a
stiff upper lip façade pretending to remain a world power in its
de
facto role
of an US client state, a mere water boy on a power team. It did
get some benefits from the Cold War
which was in no small way engineered by Churchill, exploiting the
insecurity
and paranoid of Truman to keep a crippled Britain a minor player in the
power
game of post-war global geopolitics.
Bretton Woods called
for a Bank for Reconstruction (now known
as the World Bank) to finance investment in the post-war era, an
International
Stabilization Fund to repair the flaws in the interwar gold standard:
to make
explicit and to enforce the rules of behavior expected of trading
nations, to
manage exchange rates, to assist in resolving temporary balance of
payments problems
(the key operative word is temporary, not persistent), to encourage
tariff
reduction and free trade, and to control destabilizing movements of
“hot money”
across national borders, as in Mexico in 1995 and in Asia in 1997.
Keynes saw payments
imbalance as a problem for both surplus and deficit countries, both of
which
needed to be encouraged to change their domestic policies, not rely on
changing
exchange rates to paper over unsustainable imbalances. White,
representing the
US which anticipated huge trade surpluses, saw a balance of payments
deficit as
the problem that the countries running the deficit need to correct by
changing their
domestic policies.
John Maynard Keynes,
father of Keynesianism that became the
theoretical fuel for FDR’s New Deal, now an advisor to the British
Treasury,
came to Washington in July 1941, some six months before Pearl Harbor,
to
discuss with US officials the conditions for US wartime financial aid
to
Britain. The State Department gave him a
draft agreement for defense aid that would include a provision for
postwar
arrangements in which there would be no discrimination by the United
States or
the United Kingdom against imports from any other country. This
provision upset
Keynes because it meant abolishing the British imperial preference
system that
had been negotiated in Ottawa with the members of the Commonwealth in
1932.
Keynes, who had been working and writing on monetary and exchange rate
problems
since World War I and who had come to prominence after the war with his
criticisms of the reparations provisions of the Treaty of Versailles,
was
inclined, however, to look with favor on the benefits of stabilizing
exchange
rates. Keynes believed that it was
possible and desirable to have a high degree of exchange-rate stability
without
the rigidity of classical gold standard. Thus US and UK officials had a
common
starting point. Keynes, however, worried that the US might return to
the pre-New
Deal deflationary policies of the 1930s, and so favored a plan that
would give
the UK freedom to pursue domestic full employment policies without
having to be
concerned about the impact on the resultant UK balance of payments.
The policy struggle
between Keynes and White was geopolitical
in a world of finance capitalism where national wealth determined
national
power more than the reverse as in the age of imperialistic
mercantilism. The subtle economics difference between the
two plans represented a huge gulf geopolitically. The Keynes plan
fitted the need of a
financially drained British Empire upon which the sun was about to set
while
the White plan fitted the needs of a financially well-heeled US about
to
inherit the earth. British imperial
conservatives believe that the US during World War II provided aid to
Britain
on measly terms guaranteed to destroy Britain as a super power.
Skidelsky
writes (p. xx) of financial war as the “intensity and often bitterness
of the
struggle between Britain and America for post-war position which went
on under
the facade of the Grand Alliance. When the European war started,
Britain, not
Germany, was seen by most American leaders as America’s chief rival...”
He writes of how (p. xv) “Churchill fought to
preserve Britain and its Empire against Nazi Germany. Keynes fought to
preserve
Britain as a Great Power against the United States. The war against
Germany was
won; but, in helping to win it, Britain lost both Empire and
greatness...” He
writes of how (p. xxi) it was a tragedy that Hitler”s being “in charge
of a
great nation... threw Britain into the arms of America as a suppliant,
and
therefore subordinate: a subordination masked by the illusion of a
‘special
relationship’...” Skidelsky saw the
British government’s “underlying belief that the New World had to be
yoked...
to the Old” led to “the deference Britain paid to America’s wishes...
and its
failure to exploit crucial elements in its bargaining position--like
fighting a
more limited war, or even making a separate peace with Germany...” (p.
180)
Declassified
documents on war-time Allied summits provide
substantial evidence to support Skidelsky’s observations. Until
his untimely death, FDR was on a
collision course with Churchill on the “good” war’s objective
vis-à-vis British
colonialism. It was not until Truman
replaced FDR that US policy accepted British insistence on the
preservation of
the British Empire as a war aim, in the name of
anti-global-communism. This policy change greatly limited US
option
in developing a viable post war foreign policy toward new emerging
nations of
the Third World that eventually led to the Vietnam War, by
indiscriminately equating
Third War nationalism with communism.
The idea that the US
should help Britain fight to defeat a
tyranny, not to preserve an empire, is embarrassing self deception. The
US only
declared war on Germany after Pearl Harbor.
German tyranny had by then been going on for a number of years. Kristallnacht,
“the Night of Broken Glass”, took place on 9th-10th November, 1938, a
year
before Britain and France declared war on Germany on September 3, 1939,
three
years before the US entered the war. During Kristallnacht over 7,500
Jewish shops were destroyed and 400 synagogues were burnt to the ground
all
over Germany. Ninety-one Jews were killed and an estimated 20,000 were
sent to
concentration camps which until that time had been mainly for
non-Jewish political
prisoners. Prominent Americans were
actively against US involvement in Europe and many were actively pro
Germany
until after Pearl Harbor. WWII was a
conflict of geo-political interests among great powers. The
struggle against tyranny image was an
afterthought moral icing on the geopolitical cake. The “good war”
was especially good for the US
economy.
After WWII, Britain
was still saddled with many of the cost
of empire, while losing most of the benefits. Colonial natives soon
converged
on the British Isles to take advantage of liberal social programs
originally
designed for native Britons - free national service medicine and
generous unemployment
benefits. Even wealthy Third World elites would send their children to
Britain
for fancy orthodontic work and their pregnant mistresses to give birth
in
London hospitals, all for free, plus a British passport for the new
born, not
to mention generous welfare payments for the unwed mother. Aside from
the pride
of being on the “winning” side, Britain got pitifully few tangible
benefits
from the war. London and other industrial cities suffered severe damage
from Luftwaffe
air raids and the country really had been an occupied territory by US
forces
since 1942.
The other
disadvantage was that unlike Japan and Germany,
Britain actually still had a performing democracy at the end of the
war, though
hardly a working one. This prevented the
British communists from any real prospect of coming to power and thus
did not
rate serious US attention. Unlike
Germany and Japan, on which much US aid was driven by US fixation on
anti-communism, Britain had an anti-communist Labour government, the
worst of
all possible combinations in terms of post-war US geopolitical
agenda. While the US hated and feared communists,
they had even less respect for the social democrats in the Labour
Party. The US was set to teach European social democrats
a lesson and the British Empire was taken over by the US in the name of
communist containment, with the pretense that British Labour was not
trustworthy on the ideological struggle.
Of course, Ox-bridge mentality was also a factor, as many in Britain
were quick to recognize. Then there was brain drain to the US, and the
over-valued pound sterling devastated British trade. For five decades
after
WWII, British ingenuity expressed itself in pop culture rather than
independent
national revival strategy.
Immigrants from the
Commonwealth did not catch on until
years later that they could get free rides on the welfare programs In
Britain originally
designed to serve only UK residents with money collected before the war
from
distant parts of the empire. But the
programs put in place by the Labour Government stayed operative long
after
Atlee, until Thatcher. Not only Third World
residents, but US residents did the same thing.
Fulbright exchange students selected Britain mostly for its medical
benefits for all residents regardless of citizenship. The
returned US students taught their friends
how to vacation in the United Kingdom for free dental work and newborn
deliveries. Socialism cannot work unless all who draw from the system
also pay
into the system. The residual effects of
a collapsed empire were use by Margaret Thatcher to prove that social
welfare
did not work.
The Collapse of the
Bretton Woods Regime
Nixon’s 1971 declaration of “we are all
Keynesians now” had the effect of rendering modern Keynesians
monetarists,
ending four decade of polarity in economics between Keynesianism and
monetarism.
The reason modern Keynesianism cannot avoid
monetarism is because of the collapse of Bretton
Woods in 1971, which has exacerbated the monetary implications
of fiscal policy. Any government today trying to repeat Kennedy's
1960 New Economy of tax cuts and fiscal spending will face a market
assault on its currency. That is, any government except
the US because of dollar hegemony.
Nixon’s declaration
served to cover up the
impact of his historic abandonment of the Bretton
Woods regime of gold standard/fixed exchange rates on August
15, 1971, a date that marked the end of US dominance of world finance
derived from the strength of its monetary system, and put the US on a
slippery
slope of currency manipulation through dollar hegemony. To compensate
for the
dethroning of the dollar from its gold throne, Nixon imposed
ineffective wage/price control to arrest domestic inflation,
which was really an institutional measure
rather than a Keynesian one. The net result was that while wages were
kept from
rising legitimately, prices rose in the black or grey market that came
into
existence due to price-induced shortages. Paul Volcker, Nixon’s
Treasury
Undersecretary for Monetary Policy and
International Affairs, at first reassured
foreign central bankers and finance ministers that the US was merely
looking for a "breathing space" to reconstruct an orderly
monetary system. Later, Volcker admitted that the
breakdown of Bretton Woods was a failure of US
leadership and self discipline to rein in US financial excesses.
With the collapse of the Bretton Woods
regime, for the first time in the post WWII economic order, inflation
becomes exportable because of cross-border flow
of funds and the way to fight inflation was to force down wages in the
exporting economies. A government willing to dilute the value of its
currency by inflation could gain windfalls at
the expense of its trading partners by temporary
currency exchange rate and pricing advantages. With unregulated global
foreign exchange markets in the 1990s, the US was able to eventually
maintain a strong dollar without merit, through the residual historical
geopolitical arrangement of denominating oil (black gold) in dollars.
With dollar hegemony, this temporary advantage became permanent for the
US. The
US was able to devalue its currency domestically while keeping it
strong in
relation to other currencies. The boom
in the US economy was being financed by deflation in the economies of
its
trading partners.
At Bretton Woods,
Harry Dexter White
used the gold-backed dollar to appropriate a
century of British financial hegemony and to
use the gold-backed dollar as a disciplinary device to punish dishonest
fiat currencies of countries that ran recurring
deficits. It is ironic that by the 1990s, the dollar has become the
dishonest
fiat currency used by globalized currency
markets to punish honest fiat currencies of countries that accumulate
surpluses.
Milton Friedman applauded the fall of the Bretton
Woods regime in 1991, since he and other conservative
monetarists of the Chicago School saw floating exchange rates as an
excellent
“laissez-faire” free market solution,
notwithstanding that events have since shown
that currency markets, manipulated by hedge funds that created
recurring financial crises around the globe, are anything but “free”.
Friedman, father of modern monetarism, saw the development of foreign
exchange
markets as forcing the Federal Reserve to focus on
the one thing it allegedly couldcontrol: the
domestic money supply. Friedman was
fixated on the truism of the theory and not particularly concerned with
the
practical effects on the economy from violent volatility in interest
rate that
a steady money supply would generate.
Volcker, as Fed
Chairman, influenced by a Friedman
who had been buoyant by a general wave of conservatism into guru status
among ideologue
monetarists, adopted in 1980 a “new operating
method” for the Fed as a therapeutic thunderbolt on Wall Street
which seemed to have lost faith in the Fed's political will to control
inflation. The new operating method, by concentrating on monetary
aggregates, i.e. money supply, and letting it dictate interest rate
swings
within a range from 13 to 19%, to be
authorized by the FOMC, was an exercise in“creative
uncertainty” to disrupt the financial market’s complacency about
interest rate stability or gradualism, which was widely perceived as
the key
Fed policy objective. There had been a
traditional expectation that even if the Fed were to
raise rates, it would do so at a gradual pace to avoid causing the
market to
become volatile.
The expectation of interest rate gradualism
has been again justified by
the Fed most recent “measured paced” approach to interest rate hikes in
the
final year on Greenspan’s watch.
Volcker’s failed
monetary experiment in 1980 forced the
Fed back on its old path: focusing on interest
rates and not money supply, and ironically to vow again to focus
on the long term. To avoid total economic collapse, the Fed had no
choice but
to maintain interest rate gradualism over money
aggregate stability that came with the unbearable price of interest
rate
volatility.Yet,
for the long term, money supply was the correct barometer, while
interest rate policy
was the appropriate tool for the short term. Since
interest rate volatility is
unavoidable, the compromise is to make the change in rates gradual to
reduce
the volatility. But gradualism prolongs a short-term solution into a
long term
cure, thus neutralizing the effectiveness of interest rate policy as a
short-term tool. That is the real conundrum of interest rate policy,
not the
inversed yield curve as Greenspan suggests.
The
Surviving Bretton Woods Twin Monsters
Two related
super-national institutions were organized by
the US-sponsored Bretton Woods conference: the International Monetary
Fund
(IMF) and the International Bank for Reconstruction and Development
(IBRD),
more commonly known as the World Bank. Both institutions have been
dominated by
the US since its inception, as the United Nation has been. Together,
these two
super-national agencies helped build the US global financial empire
through
world trade conducted under the auspices of the World Trade
Organization, the
rule of which are set by the strong well-developed economies to the
disadvantage of the weak developing economies.
The IMF world view
is expressed by its official statement of
its function: “During that decade [1930s], as economic activity in the
major
industrial countries weakened, countries attempted to defend their
economies by
increasing restrictions on imports; but this just worsened the downward
spiral
in world trade, output, and employment. To conserve dwindling reserves
of gold
and foreign exchange, some countries curtailed their citizens' freedom
to buy
abroad, some devalued their currencies, and some introduced complicated
restrictions on their citizens' freedom to hold foreign exchange. These
fixes,
however, also proved self-defeating, and no country was able to
maintain its competitive
edge for long. Such ‘beggar-thy-neighbor’ policies devastated the
international
economy; world trade declined sharply, as did employment and living
standards
in many countries.” This of course is a
free trade view favored by the dominant economy, such as pre-war
Britain and
post-world US.
Among the official
purposes of the IMF are: To promote
exchange stability, to maintain orderly exchange arrangements among
members,
and to avoid competitive exchange depreciation; To assist in the
establishment
of a multilateral system of payments in respect of current transactions
between
members and in the elimination of foreign exchange restrictions which
hamper
the growth of world trade; To give confidence to members by making the
general
resources of the Fund temporarily available to them under adequate
safeguards,
thus providing them with opportunity to correct maladjustments in their
balance
of payments without resorting to measures destructive of national or
international prosperity. Only 29 of the
43 conference participants signed its Articles of Agreement in 1945
because
many governments saw Bretton Woods as a US-British condominium, with
Britain
citing many of its pre-war financial hegemonic privileges to the US in
exchange
for being allowed to stay in the game. Thus when the US forced
Japan and Germany to
accept the Plaza Accord of 1985 signed by the G5 to revalue the yen and
the mark
respectively, it amounted to forcing a “competitive exchange
depreciation” of
the dollar, in violation of IMF principle. The overvaluation of the
dollar in the
1980s was the result of Federal Reserve policy under Paul Volcker, not
by
polices of the central banks of Germany or Japan. Similarly, pressure
on China in
recent years to revaluate the yuan amounted to a comparable violation
of the
same IMF principles. The fall in the purchasing power of the dollar was
the
result of Fed policy under Alan Greenspan and the unwarranted strength
of the
dollar in exchange rate reflect the effects of dollar hegemony
constructed by Robert Rubin,
US Treasury Secretary under Clinton.
Unlike the IMF whose
function was to promote international
trade with a currency stabilizing fund, the official function of the
World Bank
was to promote long-term economic development, including financing of
infrastructure projects, such as road-building and improving water
supply. The
so-called Bretton Woods twins: the IMF and the World Bank, because of
critical noises
made by Joseph Stiglitz, former World Bank chief economists who had
been forced
out by instruction from US Treasury Secretary Lawrence Summers,
appeared to be
at odds in their policy focus. But this is mere sibling rivalry.
In late 1995, in the face of threats from the
US Congress to cut US contributions to the bank, the World Bank
embarked on a
high profile advertising campaign to underline its importance to the
economies
of donor countries. The World Bank announced that, “It [the Bank]
doesn't just
lend money; it helps developing countries become tomorrow's
markets.” The US was getting back from the World Bank
more than what it put in, so the argument went.
Social welfare have
transformed into corporate welfare, with
the Bank clinging onto the party line that what is good for Northern
industry
is also good for the poor of the South. The
infamous Lawrence Summers World Bank memo, in which he, as chief
economist,
argued that the export of pollution to poor countries represented
"immaculate" economic logic because Third World lives were worth
less, is a classic example of warped neo-liberal mentality. The amount
of money it is throwing in the direction of the private sector and the
Bank’s
new belief that corporations can do development on their own, without
government involvement is manifested in the Bank's shift from project
lending
to "policy" lending in the form of loans for removing trade barriers,
privatizing government-owned companies and restructuring whole sectors
of the
economy in order to allow the entry of transnational corporations from
the
advanced economies. Private sector projects have weaker information and
disclosure policies, less accountability and less stringent
environmental
policies than public sector projects.
For example, the
World Bank has been one of the most
powerful forces behind genetic erosion around the world for the last 50
years.
This devastation has resulted from a wide range of activities in most
of the
sectors at the bank - in particular, agriculture, energy, forestry,
infrastructure and industry. In the 1950s, the Bank's agricultural
focus was on
cash crops (such as cacao, rubber and palm oil), which started the
decline of
diversity in farming systems and the crops themselves.
When the Ford Motor
Company fell into decline after founder
Henry Ford’s death in 1947, it was “saved” by the "Whiz Kids" who
managed to turn the company back toward profits by producing the worse
cars in
the industry through the application of systems approach to management
in which
the quality and safety of a product was only a trade-off component in
the quest
for profitability. The Whiz Kids were led by Robert S. McNamara who
went on to
mislead Johnson into the Vietnam War quagmire as the Secretary of
Defense who
promised to win an unwinnable war by committing more and more troops
and money,
after which he went on to become president of the World Bank (1968-81)
with
equally disastrous impact on the world's poor. McNamara's top-down
anti-poverty
strategy accelerated a process of agricultural modernization and
integration
into the global market that increased inequality, exacerbated poverty
and had a
devastating impact on biodiversity and the environment.
Ambitious
land-clearing and settlement projects were another
important component of the Bank's purported poverty alleviation
strategy in the
McNamara era. These often involved the decimation of vast areas of
prime
biodiversity habitats, particularly tropical rainforests. For example,
in the
1970s, the Bank approved a series of loans that cleared 1.3 million
acres, or
6.5%, of Malaysia's rainforests, mainly to install mono-cultural
plantations
for the production of palm oil. Such areas experienced dramatic losses
in
biodiversity: in one fell swoop, diversity plummeted from thousands of
species
per hectare to a single lonely palm tree. All told, plantation forestry
systems
cover some 15 million hectares today, and they are still
expanding.These kinds of escapades continued into the 1980s.
Brazil's
infamous Polonoreste agricultural development' program, funded by the
World Bank
to the tune of $443 million, single-handedly increased the
deforestation of the
Brazilian Amazon from 1.7% in 1978 to 16.1% in 1991. More than half the
loans
financed the paving of a 1,500 kilometers dirt track through the
rainforests of
Rondnia. Most of the rest went into constructing feeder and access
roads, and
the establishment of 39 rural settlement centers to consolidate and
attract
settlers who were to raise tree crops (mainly cocoa and coffee) for
export.
Instead of the tens of thousands of settlers anticipated, half a
million
arrived in the space of 5 years. Agricultural extension services and
credit
never materialized and resettlement officials were overwhelmed. In
order to
survive, the settlers tried, largely unsuccessfully, to grow crops such
as
rice, beans and maize in the poor soils, which would become exhausted
in a year
or two. Slash and burn went completely out of control, as the settlers
were
constantly forced to move on. Needless to say, the impact on the
fragile
rainforest environment was devastating. By the mid-1980s, the burning
of
Rondnia was identified by NASA as the single largest, most rapid
human-caused
change on earth visible from space.
Indonesia’s
Transmigration program had an equally
devastating impact on both biological and cultural diversity. Between
1976 and
1986 the Bank lent $630 million to support the movement of millions of
Javanese
people to the outlying islands. In addition, it provided an additional
$734
million for agricultural development, which either did not materialize
or was
used to provide rice which people tried, and failed, to grow in totally
inappropriate environments, razing the environment in the process. By
the late
1980s, transmigration was responsible for deforestation rates in the
fragile
forests of the outer islands reaching a rate of 5,000 square kilometers
a year.
The results of the program were particularly devastating in Irian Jaya,
one of
the world's great reservoirs of biological and cultural diversity.
Here,
transmigration was little more than an attempt to "Javanize" what the
authorities viewed as backward and disrespectful ethnic groups. The
original
plan was to match the 1 million ethnic people, belonging to numerous
tribal
groups speaking more than 200 languages, with 1 million Javanese. This
target
was never actually reached because the program proved so disastrous,
but
transmigration did have its desired effect in decimating Irian Jaya’s
social
and cultural fabric.
In the wake of the
World Bank’s advertising campaign, the US
Treasury subsequently issued a report demonstrating that in just two
years
(1993 to 1995), the World Bank and other multinational development
banks had
channeled nearly $5 billion of contracts to US firms. One major
beneficiary was
Cargill, the third largest food corporation in the world. Cargill's
1995-96
sales were a mind-boggling $56 billion, which is roughly equivalent to
the GNP
of Pakistan, Venezuela or the Philippines. Company earnings reached
almost $1
billion and profits were 34% higher than the previous year.
Bio-prospecting is
the 20th century 'politically correct'
version of the age-old practice of appropriating the genetic heritage
and
knowledge of local communities around the world. Unlike their
counterparts in
the colonial era, today's bio-prospectors (either corporations or
scientific
institutions serving their interests) recognize that they can not get
away with
raiding local communities' resources for free any more, and that they
must pay
for access to those resources. Bio-prospecting is becoming quite a boom
industry, and the World Bank has recently recognized it as a
potentially
lucrative and green investment. But the attraction of corporations, aid
agencies and funding institutions to this new industry is not shared by
the
local communities. Bio-prospecting deals have almost without exception
been
characterized by inadequate consultation with and compensation for
local communities,
and the extension of the reach of the global market, which is rarely of
benefit
to the communities involved.
In late 1993, the
IFC and the Global Environment Facility
(GEF) created quite a stir when they met with private foundations to
discuss
their interest in investing in investing money in venture capital funds
to
"exploit the knowledge stock" of traditional communities. Project
ideas included ecotourism, the screening of plants for medicinal and
other
potential applications, buying up the knowledge of traditional
communities, and
even selling the rights to "charismatic" ecosystems to large
corporations for public relations value. NGOs and local communities
responded
with outrage that the Bank, with its supposed mission of helping the
poor, would
consider investing in commercialization activities that most local
people
consider unfair, unethical and even sacrilegious.
Next: The US-China Trade Imbalance
|