China's Currency
PART III: Futures Imperfect for China
By
Henry C K Liu
Part II: Tequila Trap Beckons China
This article
appeared in AToL
on November 13, 2004
Liquidity, a fundamental concept in finance, can be defined as the
ability to buy or sell large quantities of an asset quickly and at low
cost. A liquidity crunch is the main cause of financial cycles of boom
and bust. Financial cycles are different from business cycles in that
they are predominantly driven by liquidity and illiquidity. Financial
cycles are the dominant force in finance capitalism, replacing the
business cycles in industrial capitalism.
In a bubble economy, asset values are inflated beyond the level
supported by the money supply. The abrupt monetization of assets in a
crisis requires large amounts of ready cash in the financial system.
But cash is among the lowest-yield financial instruments that are
expensive to hold. Thus the main source of cash in times of crisis is
always the central bank, which can issue money at will and at no
monetary cost, at least for the US. Other central banks cannot issue
dollars, the currency of choice in international finance. They cannot
issue money even in their own currencies without the penalty of
exposing their currencies to speculative attacks because of dollar
hegemony. The vast majority of equilibrium asset pricing models do not
consider trading and thus ignore the time and cost of transforming
financial assets into cash or vice versa. The history of recent
financial crises suggests that at times market conditions can be so
severe that liquidity can decline or even disappear temporarily. Such
liquidity shocks are a potential channel through which asset prices are
influenced by liquidity.
Bond
of bother
The current yield environment more closely resembles 1994 than 1987. In
1994, the bond market was caught on the wrong side of economic
fundamentals by the Fed's low-interest policy and crashed with Fed
policy reversal toward higher rates. But unlike 1987, the stock market
was spared in 1994 because money merely left bonds for stocks. Yet
stock prices eventually need to be supported by corporate earnings,
which will be the Achilles' heel of any equity bubble because rising
interest rates tend to dampen corporate earnings. In a situation when
both bonds and stocks face price collapse, market participants may
simply hold on to cash in an attempt to preserve capital. In that case,
central banks face what Keynes calls a liquidity trap and become
impotent in curing a financial crisis with added liquidity. The last
victim of a liquidity trap was Japan in the late 1990s when banks could
not find creditworthy borrowers, even with negative interest rates.
For 2004, many traders view the rout in bond prices as merely the
unwinding of an overbought unbalance caused by interest rates staying
too low for too long. Bond portfolios are mostly still above water for
the year, although they lost much of their earlier gains. By historical
standards, the rise in interest rates since June 13 can be considered
extreme, at least in percentage terms.
The policy of using interest rate cuts to pump up demand incurs
economic costs, as evidenced first in Japan and then recently in the
US. The costs include the danger of structural damage to long-cycle
finance institutions such as those in the insurance sector. The
soundness of these finance institutions can be threatened by abnormal
spreads between short and long-term interest rates as well as by the
adverse effect of new debts on the value of outstanding debts. There is
also the question of sustainability and subsequently re-igniting
inflationary pressures. In other words, the Fed's low interest strategy
between 2000 and 2003 might have led to a bond bubble similar to the
equity bubble of the 1990s, and its subsequent reversal on interest
strategy creating conditions that ensure the bond bubble will burst.
Long-term yields have fallen to a level that requires a prolonged
period of price stability or deflation to justify. Five-year yields
slightly above 2% require zero inflation in the US economy over the
next five years, a clearly unlikely scenario, particularly so with
commodities and oil. US bonds have risen further and faster than at any
stage in the past 40 years, a phenomenon that looks jarringly like the
Nasdaq run-up of the late 1990s which hit its all-time high on March
10, 2000 at 5132.52. The heavily tech-dependent index would fall more
than 77.8% in the three years after the bottom dropped out of the
so-called Internet bubble. It now hovers around 1900. Since February
2000, the decline in five-year yields is down from 6.76% to 2.08%,
which was greater in percentage terms (68%) than the 59% drop from
September 1981 to August 1986 that set the scene for the 1987 crash.
Before 1994, short-term rates fell from 8% to 5% only to climb back to
8% again. Today, 10-year yields have risen from below 3.5% to over 4%
and can rise above 5% over an 18-month period. Yet volatility seems
built into the market. Ten-year yields again fell below 4%, hitting
3.984% on October 22, 2004. Unsophisticated investors traditionally are
lured into bonds as a safe investment when in fact the potential for
capital loss in bonds is just as great as in equities in the new
economy. Bonds tend to produce a lower return because they are
perceived to be less risky than equities. Yet on a three- or five-year
view ahead, this perception will be wrong due to the Fed's interest
rate vicissitudes. There is at least a possibility of 10-year bonds
falling by 25% over the next 18 months as there is of shares falling by
the same amount. The threat to bonds even if there is no resurgence of
inflation will be that other investments will outperform them in a
neutral interest rate environment, putting downward pressure of bond
prices. Yet most investors in bonds do not have that same awareness of
risk as equity investors.
The consequences of a bond market crash are complex and generally not
well understood. That it hurts pension funds and forces governments to
borrow at higher rates is obvious. Less obvious is that it also
distorts bank balance sheets and is lethal to the financial sector. US
Fed chairman Alan Greenspan has expressed the view that markets are now
more sophisticated and better hedged than in 1994. But the US now
depends more on foreign savings. The market for mortgage-backed
securities has tripled in a decade to $4.7 trillion. Participants in
that market hedge their bets in the bond market, amplifying bond market
moves. Even slight interest rate moves by the Fed may have a bigger and
less predictable impact as a result.
Swap
to power
The US twin deficits are showing no signs of abating with Greenspan
reassuring the market that the US economy is in "reasonably good
shape". Derivatives such as total return swaps (TRS) can make
short-term dollar loans (liabilities) appear as portfolio investments
(assets). Also, the requirement to meet margin or collateral calls on
derivatives may generate sudden, large foreign exchange flows that
would not be indicated by the amount of foreign debt and securities in
a nation's balance of payments accounts. As a result, the balance of
payments accounts no longer serve well for assessing country risks. As
China liberalizes it credit markets, or pushes the yuan into the global
credit markets, its $450 billion-plus foreign exchange reserves will
appear less significant as a hedge against speculative attacks on the
yuan.
In the event of currency devaluation or sharp downturns in securities
prices, derivatives such as foreign exchange forwards and interest rate
swaps and TRS function to quicken the pace and deepen the impact of the
crisis. Derivative transactions with emerging market financial
institutions generally involve strict collateral or margin
requirements. The rate of collateralization is estimated at around 20%
of the notional principal of the swap. If the market value of the swap
position were to decline, the East Asian firm would have to add to its
collateral in order to bring it up to the required maintenance level.
Thus a sudden sharp fall in the price of the underlying security would
occur at the beginning of a devaluation or a broader financial crisis
would require the Asian firm to immediately add dollar assets to its
collateral in proportion to the loss in the present value of the swap
positions. This would trigger an immediate outflow of dollar reserves
as local currency and other assets are exchanged into dollars in order
to meet the collateral requirements. This would not only quicken the
pace of the crisis, it would also deepen the impact of the crisis by
putting further downward pressure on the exchange rate and asset
prices, thus increasing losses to the financial sector. An upward
revaluation of the yuan may well produce such instability all over
Asia.
The EU's GDP is now greater than the US's. Yet the euro economy is
still much smaller than the dollar economy due to dollar hegemony. The
pool of euro-dollars (off-shore dollars) in circulation is now larger
that of dollar circulation within the US. The introduction of the euro
led to a surge in euro-denominated bond issues, and this in turn
boosted arbitrage and hedging activity by issuers, dealers and
investors. Participants in European markets began to use interest rate
swaps to hedge their holdings of non-government bonds in the early
1990s, several years before participants in the dollar and other
markets began to do so. At that time, financial institutions were the
dominant non-government issuers in European markets, and as a result
quality conditions in the non-government bond market were similar to
those in the swap market. Participants in European markets thus became
accustomed to hedging credit products with swaps.
The growth of the euro swap market was driven by hedging and
positioning activity. Following monetary union, swaps quickly gained
benchmark status in euro financial markets, displacing some of the
benchmarks in the legacy currencies as the locus for price discovery
about future short-term interest rates.
The fragmented nature of European government securities markets
strengthened the incentive to switch to swaps for speculating on and
hedging against interest rate movements. The market for unsecured
inter-bank deposits was among the first euro financial markets to
become integrated and, given that swap rates embody expectations of
future inter-bank rates, this contributed to the rapid integration of
swap markets in the euro legacy currencies. In fact, a single euro swap
curve emerged almost overnight. Therefore, short positions - those
taken in expectation of an increase in interest rates - can be created
with relative ease in the swap market by choosing the "pay fixed" side
of a swap.
In contrast, the secured market, specifically the general collateral
repo market, was slower to break out of the segmentation that
characterized it prior to monetary union. Differences in governments'
credit ratings, settlement systems, tax regimes and market conventions
remain obstacles to the complete integration of euro government
securities markets. As a result, a single market for general collateral
repos does not yet exist; market participants must still specify the
nationality of government debt used as collateral before they conclude
a repo transaction. This complicates the use of government securities
to hedge or speculate on interest rate movements.
The switch to swaps was reinforced by a series of traumatic market
events in the late 1990s. Events surrounding the near collapse of
Long-Term Capital Management in September 1998 highlighted the risks
inherent in the use of government bonds and related derivatives to
hedge positions in non-government securities. This had been a routine
strategy among dealers up until that time, albeit more so in the dollar
market than in the euro market.
Squeezes in German government bond futures contracts over 1998-2002 had
a similar effect. Temporary increases in the scarcity premium on euro
government securities during auctions of third-generation mobile
telephone licenses in 2000 also made government securities less
attractive for hedging and position-taking purposes.
Overnight index swaps (OISs) have become especially popular hedging and
positioning vehicles in euro financial markets. An OIS is a
fixed-for-floating interest rate swap with a floating rate leg tied to
an index of daily inter-bank rates. In the euro market, OISs are
overwhelmingly referenced to the euro overnight index average (EONIA)
rate - a weighted average of interest rates contracted on unsecured
overnight loans in the euro area inter-bank market. Trading in EONIA
swaps is highly concentrated in maturities of three months or less, and
EONIA swap rates are widely considered to be the preeminent benchmark
at the short end of the euro yield curve. Banks, pension funds,
insurance companies, money market mutual funds and hedge funds all make
extensive use of EONIA swaps to hedge and speculate on short-term
interest rate movements. OISs are also traded in US dollars and other
major currencies, but they have not gained benchmark status in these
markets.
The benchmark status of the euro swap curve is reflected in quoting
practices for corporate bonds. These practices often depend on the
credit quality of the issuer and the nationality of the investor.
Euro-denominated bonds issued by investment grade borrowers are usually
quoted in terms of a spread over the swap curve. For non-investment
grade corporate bonds, prices are quoted in the form of outright
yields. Interest rate swaps are becoming more widely used as benchmark
instruments in the US dollar market too. However, the shift is less
advanced than in the euro market. For example, many US investors still
prefer to price dollar-denominated corporate bonds against the treasury
yield curve rather than the swap curve.
Notwithstanding the growth of the euro swap market, futures contracts
continue to be heavily used as hedging and positioning vehicles.
Indeed, trading in euro-denominated money and bond market futures
soared in the run-up to and years immediately following the
introduction of the single currency. Contracts based on three-month
Euribor - a trimmed average of interest rates quoted for term deposits
in the euro area inter-bank market - and traded on the London
International Financial Futures and Options Exchange (LIFFE) are by far
the most actively traded short-term interest rate futures in the euro
market. Contracts based on German government securities and traded on
Eurex dominate activity in longer-term euro futures.
The growth of the euro swap market has been accompanied by greater
diversity in the range of players using interest rate swaps. In the
run-up to European monetary union, the inter-dealer segment drove the
growth of the euro swap market. At end-1998, positions vis-ŕ-vis other
dealers accounted for 52% of the outstanding notional amount of euro
interest rate swaps and forwards. Since 1999, the dealer-customer
segment has become increasingly important. By end-June 2002, positions
vis-a-vis financial customers accounted for 42% of the outstanding
notional amount of euro interest rate swaps and forwards, and positions
vis-a-vis non-financial customers a further 7%. By comparison, in the
dollar swap market, positions vis-a-vis financial customers accounted
for 41% of outstanding contracts, and positions vis-a-vis non-financial
customers 15%. The smaller share of the dollar swap market accounted
for by inter-dealer positions - 45%, compared to 51% in the euro market
- is explained in part by greater concentration in the dollar market,
which results in dealers offsetting more of their transactions
internally rather than with other dealers.
Even European governments have begun to use interest rate swaps to
manage their risk exposures. The French government has since October
2001 employed swaps to shorten the average maturity of its debt. As of
end-July 2002, it had written swaps totaling 61 billion euro in
notional principal, equivalent to approximately 8% of the outstanding
French government debt. The German government uses swaps to lower its
interest costs. At present, it is authorized to swap up to 20 billion
euro, equivalent to about 3% of its outstanding debt. The Dutch,
Italian and Spanish governments are also active in the euro swap
market. The entry of governments into the interest rate swap market has
tended to put a ceiling on euro swap spreads.
Although the range of players using swaps is increasing, the number of
intermediaries is declining. Swaps are overwhelmingly traded over the
counter (OTC), and so dealers are critical to the functioning of the
swap market. Given customers' traditional preference for dealing with
high-quality counterparties, trading in OTC markets has long been
dominated by a handful of better-rated dealers. In particular, the
major dealers have tended to be commercial banks with credit ratings of
at least double-A.
In recent years, intermediation in OTC markets has become even more
concentrated owing to mergers and acquisitions. For example, following
the merger of Chase Manhattan and JP Morgan in 2000, the combined
entity's share of the global OTC interest rate derivatives market
equaled approximately 25%. In the EONIA swap market, the five largest
dealers accounted for 48% of all trading activity during the second
quarter of 2001 and the 20 largest dealers 88%. Other segments of the
euro interest rate swap market were more concentrated, with the five
largest dealers accounting for 60% of turnover. The euro swap market,
however, is less concentrated than the dollar market. Two banks hold
nearly three quarters of all interest rate derivative contracts booked
by US banks, and the five largest banks hold over 90% of outstanding
contracts.
Banks headquartered in the euro area are the most active dealers in the
euro swap market, writing 46% of notional contracts outstanding in
end-June 2002. Among euro area banks, German banks are the largest
dealers, with a 21% market share, followed by French banks at 15%. US
banks' share of the euro swap market was 35% at end-June 2002. In
comparison, US banks' share of the dollar swap market was 54%. Japanese
banks play only a marginal role in the euro and dollar swap markets but
have a 33% share of the yen market.
The pricing of interest rate swaps in general depends on the interest
rate used for the floating rate leg of the contract. The yield used for
the fixed rate leg is supposed to embody expectations about the future
path of the floating rate for the life of the contract and the risk
associated with the volatility of that rate. For euro swaps, the choice
of the floating rate tends to depend on the contract's maturity. For
short-dated swaps, EONIA is the most common basis for the floating rate
leg. Euribor was commonly referenced following monetary union but by
2000, had been superseded by EONIA at the short end of the swap curve.
For longer-dated swaps, Euribor remains the key reference rate. The
underlying instruments for both EONIA and Euribor are unsecured
interbank deposits and therefore these rates reflect a degree of credit
risk. Indeed, most banks in the EONIA and Euribor contributor panels
are rated double-A.
The pricing convention for euro swaps is to provide quotes in terms of
the yields that specify the fixed payments for the contracts. This is
unlike the convention for US dollar swaps, which are typically quoted
in terms of spreads over US treasury yields. Hence, the price of a
five-year euro swap might be quoted as 4%, without any reference to a
government bond yield, while that of a five-year US dollar swap might
be quoted as 50 basis points over the five year US treasury yield. To
be more precise, quoting in spreads for dollar swaps is conventional
for dealers in New York, while quoting in yields for this contract
would be more typical for dealers in London. EONIA and Euribor are the
most common reference rates. Swap rates include a premium for
counterparty risk
In spite of the benchmark status of euro swaps, their yields still tend
to hover above the yields for the most liquid triple-A rated government
bonds in a given maturity, just as dollar swap yields tend to be higher
than US treasury yields. At the 10-year maturity, for example, the
fixed rate on euro swaps at end-January 2003 was about 20 basis points
above the yield on the German bund. Swap rates are typically higher
than rates on triple-A rated securities because they contain a premium
for counterparty credit risk, which is often associated with the major
dealers in the market.
Alternatively, deterioration in the perceived creditworthiness of the
government could result in a narrowing of the spread. For example,
fiscal difficulties in Germany appeared to contribute to a narrowing of
the spread between euro swaps and German government bonds in 2001 and
2002. In the past, a customer could mitigate counterparty risk by
spreading positions across several dealers. As consolidation in the
financial industry reduced the number of active swap dealers and credit
ratings of the remaining dealers were downgraded, daily settlement and
especially collateralization became increasingly common. The widespread
use of such mechanisms for mitigating counterparty risk resulted in
narrower and more stable swap spreads.
Nevertheless, counterparty risk can still at times unsettle the swap
market. For example, credit concerns about several large US banks -
including major derivatives dealers - caused dollar and, to a lesser
extent, euro swap spreads to widen in July 2002. Other possible
influences on swap spreads include the general level of interest rates
and the slope of the yield curve. However, the economic rationale
behind these factors is difficult to explain, and their relationship
with spreads tends to be unstable over time. Liquidity was a concern in
the past but liquidity in the euro swap market is now such that yields
tend not to be driven by imbalances in supply and demand.
Rising
Europe
European swap markets were already quite liquid prior to monetary
union, and they gained liquidity following the introduction of the
single currency. The use of interest rate swaps by some market
participants as hedging and positioning vehicles increased the
willingness of other participants to do likewise, resulting in a
self-reinforcing process whereby liquid markets become more liquid.
A liquid market is one where participants can rapidly execute
large-volume transactions with a small impact on prices. There are at
least three dimensions to market liquidity: tightness, depth and
resiliency. Tightness refers to the difference between buying and
selling prices. Depth relates to the size of trades possible without
moving market prices. Resiliency denotes the speed with which prices
return to normal following temporary order imbalances.
Collateralization is increasingly common.
Euro swaps are one of the most liquid instruments available in euro
financial markets. Indeed, EONIA swaps are the most liquid segment of
the euro money market. EONIA swaps of 2 billion euro are regularly
traded in the inter-dealer market for maturities up to three months,
and significantly larger trades are not uncommon. Bid-ask spreads are
typically 1 basis point. The Triennial Central Bank Survey of Foreign
Exchange and Derivatives Market Activity shows that the average daily
turnover of euro-denominated OTC interest rate contracts almost doubled
between April 1998 and April 2001, to 231 billion euro. Compared to the
$56 trillion in notion value of dollar derivative in 2002, the euro
derivative market is still miniscule.
By 2001, the turnover of euro swaps and forwards exceeded that of all
interest rate products other than money market futures, US treasuries
and German government securities. Trading in EONIA swaps appears to
account for much of this growth. Beyond two years, however, the euro
swap market is neither as tight nor as deep as the larger European
government securities markets. Anecdotal evidence suggests that bid-ask
spreads for euro swaps are wider than those for government securities:
one basis point for inter-dealer swaps, compared to less than half a
basis point for the most recently issued German government securities.
Quote sizes are also smaller: approximately 100 million euro for five
and 10-year swaps, compared to at least 150 million euro for the most
recently issued German bobls (or Bundesobligationen) and bunds. Trading
activity in longer-dated swaps is a fraction of that in futures
contracts on German government bonds.
Moreover, liquidity in the euro swap market appears more likely to
evaporate during periods of extreme volatility than liquidity in the
larger government securities markets. In particular, interest rate
swaps remain less liquid than they would be if they were traded on an
organized exchange, where a central clearing house could act as the
counterparty to all trades. Counterparty credit risk becomes of
paramount concern during periods of market volatility, when uncertainty
about the health of financial institutions often increases.
Consequently, arrangements for dealing with counterparty risk play a
major role in determining market liquidity under stress.
Assuming that the soundness of the clearing house is ensured, the
liquidity of instruments traded on organized exchanges tends to be more
robust to stress than that of instruments traded over the counter.
Steps have been taken to encourage greater centralization in the swap
market. In the early part of 2001, the London Clearing House, supported
by several of the largest swap dealers, began clearing and settling
interest rate swaps in all of the major currencies. At about the same
time, LIFFE introduced futures contracts on two-, five- and 10-year
euro swaps. However, trading of swap futures accounts for an
insignificant proportion of global swap activity. In contrast, trading
of futures contracts on German government bonds accounts for the larger
part of activity in the German government securities market. EONIA
swaps are the most liquid segment of the euro money market, but
government securities markets are more liquid at longer maturities.
It remains unclear whether swaps will continue to erode the benchmark
status of government securities and consolidate their position as the
dominant positioning and hedging vehicles in euro fixed-income markets.
In addition to the previously mentioned concern about counterparty
risk, another concern is that the participation of large, one-sided
players such as governments could increase the risk of idiosyncratic
movements in swap yields - ie it could increase basis risk - and so
make swaps less effective hedges.
Repos could eventually compete with EONIA swaps for benchmark status at
the short end of the euro yield curve, as they do in the US dollar
market. European repo markets are growing rapidly and steadily becoming
more integrated, boosted in large part by market participants' efforts
to limit counterparty credit exposures. The development of a tri-party
repo market - in which settlement and management of the collateral is
delegated to a central clearing house - is especially noteworthy
because it allows a basket of securities to back a transaction,
including lower-quality, less liquid securities. At the longer end of
the yield curve, government securities remain attractive benchmark
instruments, not least because of the tremendous liquidity of German
government futures contracts.
It seems the one thing that emerges from a discussion on the
relationship of interest rate to inflation is that clear definitions of
economic condition are necessary to fully understand or describe such
relationship. Although it is not a derivative instrument until it is
structured as a swap, interest is a derivative whose value is derived
from the amount of the loan principal and the interest rate. The
interest rate determines the amount of interest to be paid over time on
a principal sum that in turn determines the size of the cash flow. The
total cash flow in a financial system reflects its liquidity. Thus
interest rate has a direct effect on liquidity.
In a debt-free economy, interest rate is irrelevant because with zero
principal, the interest payment is also zero, regardless of the
interest rate. In a saturated debt market, as in Japan now, the
interest rate is also relatively irrelevant because all outstanding
loans are mostly likely fully hedged and new loans are not being
written for lack of demand or creditworthiness common in a liquidity
trap. The zero interest rate in Japan has little impact on the economy
because qualified borrowers cannot be found even at negative rate. In
other words, outstanding bad loans have already absorbed all available
collateral.
Thus it follows that the impact of interest rate on inflation is a
function of the size of the aggregate debt in an economy in relation to
the market value of the collateral. Aggregate demand for new debt is a
function of surplus collateral which is in turn a function of market
value. A sudden and drastic fall in market value increases the loan to
asset ratio and depletes surplus loan to asset ratio. Therein lies the
detonator for implosion of a debt economy in a bear market.
What is a bear market? Price is no doubt the intended intersection of
supply and demand, provided supply and demand are defined broadly
without excluding externalities. But price does not always lead to
transactions. And only transactions make a market, not price. There is
sometime a price with no market when the asking price is stubbornly too
high to attract buyers. In an open market, technical analysts will tell
you that when an item is put up for sale, the price is not set by the
seller or the potential buyer. Price is the result of open bids,
adjusted according to the degree of market friction. What produces a
bear market is the absence of bids, the seller in a non-monopoly then
lowers the asking price out of fear that another seller may steal the
sale. Potential buyers hold back in hope for a more desperate seller.
Thus a bear market emerges. Sellers do not compete with buyers, but
with other sellers, the same being true with buyers.
A bull market is created by reverse dynamics. Buyers pay asking price
or offer above asking price out of fear of losing the deal. Sellers
hold back for better offers from competing buyers. If the upward price
pressure is greater than interest cost, potential sellers will borrow
against the asset rather than sell. This tends to increase the market
value of the asset, qualifying it for additional loans, which in turn
pushes prices up further. This is what is known as the wealth effect on
debt. This spiral could go on forever if it were not for the little
problem of interest payment. Loans are not allowed to postpone interest
payments. When that happens it is called a default, the worst word in
the credit business. Just as the concept of forgetfulness depends on
the concept of memory, the notion of debt is dependent on its service
and repayment. A debt without the support of regular or pre-arranged
interest payment or the prospect of principal amortization turns into a
loss. Thus loans rely not just on collateral, but also on the cash flow
that the collateral or other assets can generate for servicing the loan
by paying interest periodically or at an agreed time. This little
convention prevents the existence of perpetual bubbles.
There will come a point when the cash flow capacity of assets will fail
to support the interest payments on a ballooning loan perfectly secured
by the underlying assets' rising market value. When that happens, the
borrower must sell to reduce his debt and the upward price pressure
peaks and starts reversing itself as downward price pressure. The bull
market then abdicates and the bear market takes over. The nature of the
credit market is such that the downward slide is much more forceful and
speedy than the upward climb. The rapid downward slide is called a
burst of the debt bubble or a debt collapse.
Now, history has shown that two related developments could under normal
conditions prevent or soften a debt collapse. They are, first, a
sufficient and timely increase of the money supply by the central bank
and subsequently reflation that is brought about by increased money
supply in a no-growth or negative-growth economy, or inflation which is
caused by a money supply growth rate ahead of economic growth rate.
Anatomy
of money supply
The money supply then is of critical importance to monetary policy
considerations. To monitor the money supply, the Fed tracks three
monetary aggregates, M1, M2, and M3, each of increasing scope but
decreasing rate of turnover. M1 comprises the traditional definition of
money as a means of payment. It includes currency in circulation plus
the checkable deposits in depository institutions (banks and thrifts).
Currency in bank vaults and bank deposits at the Fed are not a part of
M1, although they are part of the monetary base, sometimes designated
M0. M2 includes M1 plus retail non-transaction time deposits. M3
includes M2 and wholesale deposits. Each of these money aggregates
serves a different purpose for Fed deliberations. At the end of August
2004, M1 measured $1.34 trillion; M2 measured $6.3 trillion and M3
$9.28 trillion, which increased by $390 billion over the $8.89 trillion
measured at the end of August 2003. Yet the latest available data on
notional values of dollar derivative is $56 trillion for 2002, up from
$45 trillion in 2001. The figure could reach $65 trillion for 2003 that
would be more than seven times the M3.
Too much money in relation to the output of goods and services leaves
money idle and tends to push interest rates down and push prices and
inflation up. Inflationary growth in turn requires more money to
sustain growth. Too little money tends to push interest rates up,
lowers prices and output and causes unemployment and idle plant
capacity, which in turn further reduces demand for money. There was a
time when the money in deposits with commercial and saving banks
roughly equaled to loans outstanding in the economy. The Fed, through
setting the cost of funds (interest rate), partial reserves and capital
requirements for banks, could manage the rise and fall of the money
supply.
The Fed still attempts to manage the money supply by setting bank
reserves and the discount rate at which banks borrow to meet their
reserves needs, as well as Open Market Operations to achieve Fed funds
rate (ffr) targets by trading government securities to inject or drain
money in the banking system. The Fed also participates in the repo
market to keep the repo rate in line with the ffr. Repos allow banks to
skirt the reserves requirement when expanding their loan portfolios.
Banks often do not even own the government securities they use to
execute repos, the proceeds of which yield banks such interest rate
spread from bank loans that the cost of borrowing the government
securities are more than covered.
With deregulation, all money except cash has become interest bearing.
And with Automatic Teller Machines (ATM) and credit card use, the
amount of cash needed in the economy has shrunk dramatically. Everyone
is operating with just-in-time cash management. M2 is overnight repos,
overnight eurodollars, savings accounts under $100K and money market
mutual fund shares. M3 is M2 plus time deposits over $100K and term
repos. Finally, L (Long-term liquid funds) is M3 plus T-bills, savings
bonds, commercial papers, bankers acceptances and eurodollar holding of
US residents (non-bank). Derivatives are not included in money supply
data.
With the growth of securitization, banks pass off their loan portfolios
to investors in the credit markets. In this process, banks act as
reverse intermediaries from their traditional retail role in both
deposit and loans and become retail marketers of loans to feed a
wholesale credit market. This credit market is totally outside the
control and jurisdiction of the Fed. Tax deductibility of interest on
home mortgages, interest on margin accounts, interest on loans for
corporate mergers and acquisitions affects significantly the impact of
interest rates on inflation.
Risk
business
Risk arbitrage is a risky play to profit from the simultaneous purchase
of stock in a company being acquired and sale of stock in its proposed
acquirer. It is also known as takeover arbitrage, a play that profits
by cashing in on the expected rise in the price of the target's shares
and drop in the price of the acquirer's price. The risk is if the
takeover falls through for any number of reasons, the arbitrageur may
be left with huge losses. Risk arbitrage differs from risk-less
arbitrage, which entails locking into profit from differences in the
prices of two securities or commodities trading on different exchanges.
Risk arbitrage is done through credit, using the current market value
of the shares as collateral.
Risk aversion is not just an attitude, it is a calculable premium.
Given the same return with different risk alternatives, a rational
investor will seek the security offering least risk, or conversely, the
higher the risk, the higher the demanded return. In the credit market,
instruments are all priced precisely and with uniform standards to
reflect risk aversion. Risk-based capital ratio is a minimum ratio of
estimated total capital to estimated risk-weighted assets, required by
FIRREA (Financial Institution Reform and Recovery Act). The benchmark
for risk-free return is the three-month treasury bill. The CAPM
(capital asset pricing model) used in modern portfolio theory has the
premise that the return on a security is equal to the risk-free return
plus a risk premium.
The ideal of a transaction is to be risk-less. A risk-less transaction
guarantees a profit to the trader that initiates it. An arbitrageur may
lock in a profit by trading on the difference in prices for the same
security or commodity in different markets due to market inefficiency.
For instance, if gold is selling for $450 at NY and $449.86 in London
briefly due to market inefficiency, a trader who acts with electronic
speed may buy a contract in London while simultaneously selling a
contract in NY, yielding a risk-less profit. These transactions serve a
function in eliminating market inefficiency. Risk-less transaction is
also a concept used in evaluating whether dealer mark-ups and
mark-downs on OTC (over the counter) transactions with customers are
reasonable or excessive. Nasdaq uses the 5% rule, meaning mark-ups
(when customer buys) and mark-downs (when customer sells) should not
exceed 5%.
Uncertainty is not measurable, but risk is a measurable possibility of
losing or not gaining value. The most common risks in finance are
inflation risk, interest rate risk and exchange rate risk. These risks
are interlinked in complex relationships. Other business risks are
inventory risk, liquidity risk, actuarial risk, regulatory risk,
political risk, credit risk, risk of principal and underwriting, and
guarantor risks. Risk-adjusted discount rate in portfolio theory and
capital budget analysis is the rate necessary to determine the present
value of an uncertain or risky stream of income. In the so-called New
Economy of the 1990s, this discount has been thrown out the window and
replaced by fantastic premiums. It is useful to remember that interest
rate is the cost of money at an annual rate, interest itself is the
cost of using money (debt) over time. The cost of availability of money
is a standby fee. Money not used is interest-free, regardless of
interest rate.
Interest rate risk exists when changes in interest rate will adversely
affect the value of an investor's securities portfolio. For example,
holders of long term bonds or utility stocks assume a significant
interest rate risk because the value of those bonds or utility stocks
will fall if interest rates rise. Interest rate risks can be hedged by
buying interest rate futures or interest rate options contracts. It is
useful to understand that futures and option contracts are not market
prediction, but market implications that are precisely calculable.
Interest-sensitive stocks are those of firms whose earnings change when
interest rates change, such as banks, insurance companies, financial
companies or utilities.
Bank participation in derivative markets has risen sharply in recent
years. Average daily global turnover in OTC derivatives markets
increased to $1.2 trillion in April 2004, a rise of 112% at current
exchange rates and 77% at constant exchange rates as compared to April
2001. OTC derivatives are traded outside exchanges between private
counterparties. The notional value of derivative contracts held by all
insured commercial banks in the US increased from $6.8 trillion in 1990
to $11.9 trillion in 1993, an increase of 75%, to $45.1 trillion at the
end of 2001 and $56 trillion at the end of 2002, and continues to grow
dramatically. Nearly 81% of the $56 trillion notional value of
derivatives represents interest rate derivative contracts at just 5
dealer banks.
The top five derivatives dealers hold 93% of total notional values.
More than 86% of these dealers' holdings are interest rate contracts.
Therefore, in terms of the derivatives risk matrix, a vast majority of
commercial bank derivative activity is in interest rate contracts at a
few dealer banks. These dealers conduct derivative activities as part
of their total trading operations, which makes analyzing derivative
risk difficult to isolate from total trading risk. Furthermore, if a
bank is speculating in derivatives, it occurs within these trading
portfolios and is not reported separately. A major concern facing
policymakers and bank regulators today is the possibility that the
rising use of derivatives has increased the risk profile of individual
banks and of the banking system as a whole. The global nature of
derivative markets and firms' participation in them suggests that a
disruption in these markets could have wide-ranging effects that would
be transmitted across national boundaries.
While the number of banks reporting derivative securities use declined
from 587 to 369 during by 2001, the dollar volume of assets of the
banks utilizing derivatives increased from $2.3 trillion to $5
trillion. This represents about 77% of all commercial bank assets. In
2001, the 25 largest banks in the US accounted for 99% of bank-held
derivative securities. Bank mergers have since reduced the number to
five. The smaller banks that used derivative securities utilize them
for purposes of hedging 75% of the time.
On the other hand, the top 25 banks held most of their derivatives for
trading; at the end of 2001, only 0.6% of the derivatives held by these
giant banks were held as hedges. The remaining 344 banks utilizing
derivative securities held close to 60% of the notional value of
derivatives for hedging purposes; compared with 70% in 1999. The
biggest banks not only participate in the derivatives market as
end-users but also act as dealers by providing OTC derivatives for
non-financial companies. Thirteen US-based bank holding companies are
primary dealer firms in the derivative market. Derivatives held for
trading purposes are accounted for on the balance sheet at fair value,
with gains and losses reflected on the income statement.
Risk management techniques that reduce return volatility can be called
hedging, but if these same techniques are used to increase return
volatility it is generally called speculating. Derivatives not held for
trading are being used for purposes of hedging. Most derivative
contracts are not traded on organized exchanges, but are traded in the
OTC market between counterparties.
Risk management is about the creation and preservation of value rather
than the elimination or reduction of risk. Risk-based capital
requirements have been associated with a shift of assets from loans to
securities or into securitized residential mortgages, and into
off-balance-sheet activities at some banks. Less capital is required
for holding securities rather than loans and for holding residential
mortgage loans rather than commercial or consumer loans. There is
evidence that regulation had a greater impact on bank capital decisions
than did market discipline.
One of the primary methods banks use to address risk management
concerns is the implementation of value-at-risk (VaR) models. Banks
make the choice of VaR models based on the response to regulatory
penalties for violations. Banks began to use VaR models in the late
1980s to measure the risks of their trading portfolios. Both the Bank
of International Settlement Basel I Accord of 1988 and the 1996
Amendment discuss the use of VaR models. VaR is a method of assessing
financial market risk by measuring the worst expected loss over a
specified time horizon with a given level of confidence.
The Basel Committee on Banking Supervision's paper titled
"International Convergence of Capital Measurement and Capital
Standards: A Revised Framework" deals with the new capital adequacy
framework commonly known as Basel II to secure international
convergence on revisions to supervisory regulations governing the
capital adequacy of internationally active banks. The committee
intended the framework to be available for implementation by the end of
2006, but postponed it to 2007. The fundamental objective of the
committee's work to revise the 1988 accord has been to develop a
framework that would further strengthen the soundness and stability of
the international banking system while maintaining sufficient
consistency that capital adequacy regulation will not be a significant
source of competitive inequality among internationally active banks
with the concept and rationale of the three pillars (minimum capital
requirements, supervisory review, and market discipline) approach. In
developing the revised framework, the committee has sought to arrive at
significantly more risk-sensitive capital requirements that are
conceptually sound and at the same time pay due regard to particular
features of the present supervisory and accounting systems in
individual member countries.
Fed governor Ben S Bernanke in a speech before the Institute of
International Bankers in Washington DC on October 4, 2004 highlighted
two areas important for internationally active banks: (1) home-host
supervisory cooperation, and (2) the proposed bifurcated application of
Basel II in the US and the special issues it creates for cross-border
banking. Banks with significant cross-border operations have concerns
about the prospect of each national supervisor implementing Basel II in
ways inconsistent with the principle of consolidated supervision.
Bernanke observed that Basel II capital accord is not a treaty, but a
consensus that the authorities in each national jurisdiction will
inevitably apply in their own specific ways, reflecting their preferred
approaches to bank supervision and regulation.
The large number of banks with cross-border operations will continue to
fall under the consolidated supervision of their home-country
supervisors. But at the same time, each host-country supervisor is
entrusted by its own government with ensuring that legal entities
operating within its jurisdiction are operating in a sound manner with
adequate capital. The combination of global banking and sovereign
states has produced "tensions". Three aspects of Basel II may raise the
level of tension experienced by internationally active banks still
further: (1) Basel II is more complex, (2) it includes requirements for
capital to cover operational risk in addition to credit risk, and (3)
it has all the uncertainties of the new and the untested.
These issues cannot be fully avoided in a world order of sovereign
states. In contrast to the treatment for credit risk, Basel II allows
both the consolidated and the individual legal entities to benefit
fully from operational risk reduction associated with group-wide
diversification. However, host countries entrusted with ensuring the
strength of the legal entities operating in their jurisdictions will
not be inclined to recognize an allocation of group-wide
diversification benefits, given that capital among legal entities is
simply not freely transferable, especially in times of stress. US
authorities do not see implementation of the Advanced Internal Ratings
Based method for credit risk and the Advanced Management Approach for
operational risk in the US before 2008.
Theories on financial intermediation suggest that banks can minimize
the cost of monitoring information by diversifying their assets. Banks
can also use financial derivatives for hedging, which can be an
effective mechanism for controlling risks. However, there are potential
dangers if banks utilize derivatives for speculative purposes. Banks
have capital "charges" on banks that use derivative instruments, but
these capital costs are independent of whether these instruments are
used for hedging or speculative purposes. Interest is the cost of debt
and debt is part of the money supply, and in modern finance, the
biggest part. Not all debts are interest-bearing and some debts carries
negative interest either nominally or de facto due to inflation. The
acceptability of the cost of debt is generally measured against the
opportunity cost of not taking debt.
Interest rate swaps and currency swaps have seen explosive growth in
the last two decades. Interest swaps are used to reduce risk by
synthetically matching the duration of assets and liabilities of
financial institutions as interest rates get higher and more volatile.
In currency swaps, two parties sell each other a currency with a
commitment to re-exchange the principal amount at the maturity of the
deal. Originally done to get around exchange control, currency swaps
are now widely used to tap new capital markets.
The World Bank has been an active participant in currency swaps with US
corporations. An interest rate swap is an arrangement whereby
counterparties enter into an agreement to exchange periodic interest
payments based on a specified notional principal amount. Swap options
give either the payer or receiver the right but not the obligation to
enter into an interest rate at a pre-set rate within a specific period,
or the receiver the right to receive fixed payments. Often, the swaps
are further hedged with other instruments. Debts can be taken in a
number of currencies, other financial instruments and company shares.
A weak dollar policy is one that forces or allows, by government
policy, the dollar to fall in value against foreign currencies. That
means holders of dollars and dollar assets will get fewer units of
another currency in exchange for their dollars as on outcome of
government policy. A weak dollar helps US exports because it enhances
the purchasing power of holders of foreign currencies who may or may
not be foreigners. The conventional factors behind a weak dollar are:
loose US monetary policy, deteriorating confidence in the US
government, trade and/or budget deficits, relatively low interest rate
on dollar-denominated debt and/or returns on dollar assets, from both
dividends and market capitalization value.
Structured finance exerts fundament impact on the relationship between
interest rate and inflation rate. The key instrument in structured
finance is the derivative, which is a contract whose value is based on
the performance of an underlying financial asset, index or other
investment. For example, a structured note issued by a corporate may
pay interest to note holders based on the rise and fall of oil prices.
This gives the investor the opportunity to earn interest and profit
from the change in price of a commodity at the same time. In this case,
it is obvious that market price of a commodity drives interest rate and
not the reverse.
The
world of derivatives
Other derivatives are complex debt instruments. It can be a medium-term
note, in which the
issuer enters into one or more swap arrangements to change the cash
flows it is required to make. A simple form utilizing interest rate
swaps might be a three-year floating rate note paying LIBOR (London
Interbank Offer Rate) plus a premium semi-annually. The issuer arranges
a swap transaction whereby it agrees to pay a fixed semi-annual rate
for three years in exchange for LIBOR. Since the floating rate payments
(cash flows) offset each other, the issuer has synthetically created a
fixed-rate note. The risk of interest rate fluctuation is passed on to
the counterparties of both ends of the swap. Thus interest rate risk is
exchanged for counterparty risk which theoretically is less - but not
necessarily - risky.
Structured settlements are agreements to pay a designated party a
specific sum in periodic payments over an extended period, sometimes
for a lifetime without definitive end, instead of a lump sum. The risk
on the uncertain aggregate payout amount is assumed by the structure.
An ordinary option is a derivative whose value changes in relation to
the performance of the underlying stock. In their 1973 paper, "The
Pricing of Options and Corporate Liabilities", Fischer Black and Myron
Scholes published an option valuation formula that today is known as
the Black-Scholes model. It has become the standard method of pricing
options. Black and Scholes derived a stochastic partial differential
equation governing the price of an asset on which an option is based,
and then solved it to obtain their formula for the price of the option.
Black and Scholes made indispensable contribution to the growth of the
option market by providing a mathematical calculation for precise
pricing of an option, changing it from mysterious prediction to
rational implication. A more complex example of an option would be a
futures contract, where the option value varies with the value of the
futures contract, which in turn varies with the value of an underlying
commodity or security. Derivatives on the performance of assets,
interest rates, currency exchange rates and various domestic and
foreign indices are common. A key characteristic of derivatives is its
ability to exploit leverage, which when used knowledgeably, can enhance
returns for investors and be useful in hedging portfolios. In the
1980s, abuses in program trading became notorious and in the 1990s,
when the protective strategy of portfolio insurance was distorted to
mask systemic risk, leading to huge losses for hedge funds, mutual
funds, municipalities, corporations, banks, financial institutions and
investment banking houses. These astronomical losses resulted from
unexpected movements in interest rates, caused by central bank fiats
and exchange rate tumults, adversely affecting the value of derivatives
when unwound.
Bear markets are prolonged periods of falling prices. Theories aside, a
bear market in stocks is usually brought on by the anticipation of
declining economic activity and deflation expectation; and a bear
market in bonds is caused by rising interest rates brought on by
inflation expectation. But there is also a market convention that a
bear market in equity pushes a bull market in bonds, caused by a flight
to quality and safety. Thus the relationships between bond prices and
equity prices are often indeterminate and complex.
A bear spread is a strategy in the options market designed to take
advantage of a fall in the price of a security or commodity. A bear
spread execution buys a combination of calls and puts on the same
security at different strike prices in order to profit as the
security's price falls. An alternative execution buys a put of short
maturity and a put of long maturity in order to profit from the
differences between the two puts as prices fall. A bear trap situation
confronts short sellers when a bear market reverses itself and turns
bullish. Anticipating further decline, the bears continue to sell and
then are forced to buy at higher prices to cover at expiration date,
especially on triple witching Fridays, third Fridays in March, June,
September, and December, in what the market calls a short squeeze. A
bear raid attempts to manipulate the price of a stock by selling large
numbers of shares shot to pocket the difference between the initial
price and the new, lower price after the maneuver. Bear raids are
illegal under SEC rules which stipulate that every short sale be
executed on an uptick (the last price higher than the price before it)
or a zero plus tick (the last price was unchanged but higher than the
last preceding different price). There are, however, enforcement
problems of this rule due to the complexity and speed of transactions
and the fact that foreign markets that trade US shares have different
rules.
Bull spreads can be executed in three varieties: Vertical spread
(simultaneous purchase and sale of the same class at different strike
prices but with the same expiration date); calendar spread (same price
but different expiration date); diagonal spread (combination of
vertical and calendar spreads). An investor who believes a stock will
rise, even if only moderately, can buy a 30 call for 1+1/2 and sell a
35 call; both options are "out of the money". The net cost of the
spread, or the difference between the premium and the based price, is
$1. If the stock rises to 35 just prior to expiration, the 35 call
becomes worthless and the 30 call is worth $5 with an investment of $1.
If the price goes down, the investor loses $1.
Defeasance in corporate finance is a technique whereby a corporation
discharges old, lower-rate debt without repaying it prior to maturity.
The corporation uses newly purchased securities with a lower face value
but paying higher interest or with a higher market value. The objective
is a cleaner, more debt-free balance sheet and increased earnings in
the amount by which the face value of the old debt exceeds the cost of
the new securities. The first time defeasance was used was in 1982 when
Exxon bought and put in an irrevocable trust $312 million of US
government securities yielding 14% to provide for the repayment of
principal and interest on $515 million of old debt paying 5.8-6.7% and
maturing in 2009. Exxon removed the defeased debt from its balance
sheet and added $131 million after tax earnings to that quarter. In
that case, high interest rates actually yielded a profit for a company
with low-rate old debts. Defeasance is now routinely used by every
corporation, confusing the impact of interest rates on short-term
profit.
Collateralized Bond Obligations (CBO) are investment grade bonds backed
by a pool of junk bonds. CBOs differ from CMOs (Collateralized Mortgage
Obligations) in that CBOs represent different degrees of credit quality
rather than different maturities. CBO underwriters package a large and
diversified pool of high-risk, high-yield junk bonds, which is then
separated into tiers. A top tier represents a higher-quality collateral
and pays the lowest interest rate; a middle-tier is backed by riskier
bonds and pays a higher rate; the bottom tier represents the lowest
credit quality and instead of receiving a fixed interest rate, receives
the residual interest payments - money that is left over after the
higher tiers have been paid.
Then there is the Z tier that is below all three upper tiers. CBOs,
like CMOs, are substantially over-collateralized and this fact, plus
the diversification of the pool backing them, earns them investment
grade bond ratings. Holders of third-tier CBOs stand to earn high
yields if the default rate in the collateral pool falls in good times
or falling rates, or lose money when the default rate rises in bad time
or rising rates. CBOs provide a way for big holders of junk bonds to
reduce their portfolio and for securities firms to tap new sources of
buyers in the junk bond market. CMOs separate their mortgage pools into
different maturity classes called tranches by applying income (payments
and prepayments of principal and interest). Tranches pay different
rates of interest and can mature in a few months or 20 years. CMOs are
usually backed by government guaranteed or other top-grade mortgages
with AAA ratings. If mortgage rates drop sharply, causing a flood of
refinancing, prepayment rates will soar and CMO tranches will be repaid
before their expected maturity.
Convertible bonds are off-balance-sheet obligations that give its
holder the privilege, but not the obligation, to exchange for
securities of the issuing company at some future date under prescribed
conditions, usually when market share value reaches a certain point.
Also, convertible bonds require the issuer to repay some or all of the
obligation if the share value of the issuer falls below a specified
level. Bond mutual funds are designed to produce current income for
shareholders. Bond funds also produce capital gain or loss when
interest rates fluctuate. Unlike the bonds they hold, these funds never
mature. Bond swap simultaneously sells one bond and purchase another,
with the motive to swap longer maturity to produce a profit; or to swap
improved yield for higher risk, or lower yield for higher quality, or
to create tax-deductible loss through the sale while purchasing a
substitute bond to preserve the investment.
It is obvious that derivatives inject elasticity if not outright
distortion in the relationship between interest rate and inflation
rate. And since the notional value of the derivative market is many
times the market value of the credit and equity markets, this
distortion now dominates markets behavior. This is one reason why the
traditional business cycle has been lengthened. It is not because of
Greenspan's magic touch. But the business cycle has not disappeared,
merely extended at a cost. The cost is a much more violent and sudden
release of built-up pressures when counterparty risks move against the
system.
The dated archives of economic literature can yield little light on the
current impact of interest rates on inflation. Anything written more
than 5 years ago must be describing conditions that bear little
resemblance to the current financial architecture and credit markets
and thus drawing theoretical conclusions that may not be relevant
except in a historical context. The debate on whether high interest
rate is inflationary or deflationary seems to be a puzzling controversy
in economics. Within the current international financial architecture,
interest rates cannot be fully understood without taking into account
their impact on exchange rates and credit markets. In a globalized
financial market, if the exchange rate is artificially sustained by
high interest rate, there is little doubt that the impact would be
deflationary on the local economy. This logic is also supported by
empirical data in recent years.
Yet, many astute economists insist that high interest rate causes
inflation, at least in the long run. Perhaps it is true that high rates
can cause inflation in closed economies, but it is no longer
necessarily true in open economies in a globalized financial market.
Interest rates are the prices for the use of money over time. These
prices do not always track the purchasing power of money, which is the
monetized expression of the market value of commodities (the
transaction price) at a specific time. The purchasing power of money
fluctuates over time, expressed by the prices of futures and options
which are functions of the uncertain elasticity between interest rates
and inflation rates.
As the price for the use of money over time rises, the general effect
will be deflationary if money is viewed as a constant store of value.
Otherwise, money will forfeit its function as a constant store of
value. On the other hand, if money is viewed as a medium of exchange,
the ultimate liquidity agent, then rising price for its use over time
is inflationary as a cost.
In any economy, money tends to play both roles, though not equally and
not consistently over time. For market participants, depending on their
positions (borrower or lender) at specific points of the economic cycle
(expanding or contracting liquidity), they will find different views of
money (exchange medium or value storer) to be to their financial
advantage. Thus borrowers generally consider high interest rate as
leading to cost inflation (bad), and lenders consider high interest
rate as slowing inflation (good up to a point). Asset deflation offers
good buying opportunities for those who have money or have access to
credit, but bad for those who hold assets but need money, and the pain
is proportional to asset illiquidity. Since most holders of ready cash
also hold assets, deflation has only limited and short-term advantage
for them. For inflation to be advantageous, continued expansion of
credit is required to keep asset appreciation ahead of cost inflation.
Defining
inflation
The problem is further complicated by the fact that inflation is
defined mostly by mainstream economics only as rising price of wages
and commodities, and not by asset appreciation. When it costs 10% more
to buy the same share of a company as yesterday, it is considered
growth - good economic news. When wages rise 5% a year, it is viewed as
inflation - bad economic news, despite the fact that the aggregate
purchasing power is increased by 5%. Therein lies the fundamental cause
of a bubble economy - growth and profit are generated by asset
inflation rather than by increased aggregate demand stimulating
aggregate supply.
Thus the relationship of interest rate to inflation is dependent on the
definition of money. But that is not the end of the story. Under
finance capitalism, inflation is not merely too much money chasing too
few goods as under industrial capitalism. Under financial capitalism,
two elements: Credit availability and credit markets have overshadowed
the traditional goods and equity markets of industrial capitalism. This
makes it necessary to re-examine the traditional relationship of
interest rate and inflation.
In a bull market, the buyer has the advantage because the buyer has the
final upside. In a bear market, the seller has the advantage because
the buyer is left holding the downside bag. Of course one must avoid
buying at the peak and selling at the bottom. And such strategies have
self-fulfilling effects, as technical analysts can readily testify.
These effects are magnified in long-run bull or bear markets that are
represented by a rising or falling sine curve. However, the buyer's
advantage in a bull market may be neutralized by the inflation that
usually accompanies bull markets. Thus a true bull market must yield
net capital gain after inflation and real interest cost, ie interest
cost after inflation. And in a deflationary bear market, the seller's
advantage is reinforced by deflation for he can repurchase at a later
date with only a fraction of his realized cash from what he sold
previously. Not only would the seller avoid additional loss of holding
the unsold asset in a falling market, the cash from the sale
appreciates in purchasing power with every passing day.
Thus money plays a passive role as a medium of exchange and an active
role as a store of value on the movement of prices. The conventional
view that inflation is caused by, or is a result of (the two are not
identical) too much money chasing too few goods then is not always
operative. This is because the availability of credit and the
operational rules of credit markets can distort the traditional
relationship. Credit markets, which have expanded way beyond
traditional credit intermediated by the banking system, operate on the
theory that money generally must earn interest, whether it is actually
put to use or not. There are of course abnormal times when money
actually earns negative interest because of government policy or
foreign exchange constraints, as in Hong Kong in the early 1990s and
Japan in 2000.
When idle money earns no interest, credit reserves dry up, because it
creates greater incentive to put money to work, ie investing it in
productive enterprises. For money to remain idly waiting for better
opportunity, interest rate must equal or exceed opportunity cost of
idle cash. Interest then acts as a penalty for idle money. When idle
money earns interest, the interest payment comes ultimately from the
central bank, which alone can create more money with no penalty to
itself, though the economy it lords over is not immune. Since late
1999, the Japanese monetary authorities have repeatedly reaffirmed
their commitment to maintaining their zero interest rate policy until
deflationary forces are dispelled. The result is a great deal of idle
money in Japanese banks with no creditworthy borrowers. Japanese savers
are foregoing interest income for increasing purchasing power of their
idle money in an unending deflationary spiral. With dollar hegemony,
the Fed can create dollars by fiat with immunity to the dollar economy,
at the expense of the non-dollar economies of the world.
Efficiency in the credit markets pushes money toward the highest use
and willingness to pay the highest interest. Thus when the central bank
tightens money supply, the market will drive up interest rate and vice
versa. Thus interest rate is a credit market index. When a central
bank, like the Fed, uses interest rate policy to manage the money
supply, it is in essence using a narrow market index to manipulate the
broader market. It is no different than the Fed fixing the Dow by
buying or selling bluechip shares to influence the broad S&P.
Central banking is incompatible with truly free financial markets.
When prices fall, one reason may be that consumers do not have money to
buy, as in most recessions with high unemployment. Or it may be the
result of potential consumers withholding their money for still lower
prices as in Japan now, and in some degree in China in 1998-2000. So
deflation is caused by too many goods trying to attract too little
money entering the market, but not necessarily too little money in the
economy. But if every seller can realize a cash surplus in a subsequent
repurchase in a bear market, where does all the surplus money go?
Obviously it goes to pay interest on the idle money waiting for a
cheaper price, reducing the central bank's need to issue more money to
carry the interest cost on idle money. The net effect is a removal of
money from the market and increase the amount of idle money in the
economy.
So deflation actually pushes up interest rates without necessarily
altering the aggregate money supply. The effect is that until prices
fall at a slower rate than the interest rate on idle money, there is no
incentive to buy. Thus deflation-driven rising interest rate creates
more deflationary pressure in a bear market. High interest rates move
more wealth from borrowers to lenders and from bottom to top in the
wealth pyramid. Moreover, the impact of high interest rate modifies
economic behavior differently in different income groups and even on
different activities within the same individual. When the prime rate
for some banks reached over 20% in 1980, credit continued to expand
explosively. The opposite happened when the Bank of Japan reduced
interest rate to zero. High rates only work to slow credit expansion if
the rates are ahead of inflation. And zero rate only works to
accelerate credit expansion if there is no deflation. So raising
interest rate to combat inflation or lowering rates to combat deflation
can be self-defeating under certain market conditions.
The availability of financial derivatives further complicates the
picture, because both interest rates and foreign exchange rates can be
hedged, obscuring and distorting the fundamental relations between
interest rates, exchange rates and inflation. The recurring global
financial crises in recent years were manifestations of this
distortion.
The theory of market equilibrium asserts that market tends to reach
"natural" equilibrium as it approaches efficiency, which is defined as
the speed and ease with which equilibrium is reached. Yet the market is
complex not only because the relationship of market elements is poorly
defined or even undefinable, but also the very instruments designed to
enhance market efficiency tend to create wide volatility and
instability. Thus a "natural" equilibrium state can, in fact, be
defined as the actual state of the fluctuating market at any moment in
time. With 24-hour trading, the notion of a milestone moment of
equilibrium is problematic. Further, the very financial instruments
created to enhance market efficiency toward its "natural" equilibrium
state make the equilibrium elusive. Such instruments are mainly
designed to manage risk generated by both broad market movements and
momentary disequilibrium.
Structured finance mainly involves unbundling financial risks in global
markets for buyers who will pay the highest price for specific
protection. Because users of these instruments look for special payoffs
through unbundling of risk, the cost of managing such risk is
maximized. This unbundling renders the notion of market equilibrium
inoperative. The unbundled risks are marketed to those with the biggest
appetite for such risks, in return for compensatory returns. Thus
market equilibrium is not any more merely a large pool of turbulent
transactions with a level surface. It is in fact a pool of transactions
with many different levels of interconnected surfaces, each serving
highly disaggregated specialty markets. Equilibrium in this case
becomes a highly complex notion making the impact and prospect of
externalities highly uncertain and unpredictable. This uncertainty and
unpredictability caused the demise of Long Term Capital Management -
the mother of high-flying hedge funds - on account of failed hedges in
a matter of days.
Interest swaps, for example, are not single purpose transactions for
managing interest risks. They can be structured as hedges against
inflation risks, or foreign exchange risks, or any number of other
financial risks to satisfy needs or provide protection. And the impact
is not limited to the two contracting parties, since each party usually
hedge again with a third counterparty. That is what makes hedging
systemic. A further irony is that the very objective to insure against
unit volatility risk by covering the market broadly increases risks of
systemic illiquidity. While each individual contract is structured with
immaculate logic and clarity, the aggregate systemic effect is totally
opaque and incomprehensible. No one really understands the magnitude of
the destructive force that can result in a chain reaction triggered by
the tiniest rupture. Under such circumstances, it's a puzzle why China
is so keen to join a system that is bent on self-destruction.
Next: China Steady on the Peg
|