Shifting
China’s
Export towards the Domestic Market
(Appearing in
AToL as CHINA’S DOLLAR MILLSTONE)
By
Henry C. K. Liu
Part I: Breaking Free
from Dollar Hegemony
Part II: Developing China with Sovereign Credit
Part III: History of Monetary Imperialism
Part IV: Gold,
Manipulation and Domination
Part V: Specific
Measures to Restore China’s National Destiny
Different nations profess different destinies at different
stages of their history. The United
States
had its Manifest Destiny of territorial expansion from the War of 1812
to the
beginning of the Civil War in 1861. In 1845, influential columnist John
L.
Sullivan published a piece entitled Annexation in the Democratic
Review, in which he urged the young United States to annex the
Republic of
Texas, composed of all of present-day Texas, plus portions of New
Mexico, Oklahoma,
Kansas, Wyoming and Colorado, because it was “our manifest destiny to
overspread the continent allotted by Providence for the free
development of our
yearly multiplying millions,” which generally excluded Native
Americans,
Mexicans and African Americans who were at the time mostly slaves.
In 1837, belligerent American settlers in the Mexican state of
Coahuila y Tejas, led by settler Sam Houston, a fugitive from
Tennessee, won independence
from Mexico in a secessionist war instigated by the US, proposed
voluntary annexation
to US President Martin Van Buren, who refused the request since the US
anticipated that it would lead to war with Mexico. Texas
then withdrew the annexation offer in 1838 to declare itself as an
independent
nation called the Republic
of Texas,
recognized by the US,
Britain,
France
and the Netherlands.
In 1843, Britain opposed US annexation of Texas, but President John
Tyler
signed the treaty of annexation with the Republic of Texas in April
1844 despite
Mexican leader Antonio Lopez de Santa Anna‘s warning that annexation
would be “equivalent
to a declaration of war.” But the US
senate overwhelmingly rejected the annexation on June 8 by a vote of 35
to 16,
failing the constitutional requirement of a two-thirds majority in the
Senate
to confirm a treaty with a foreign state.
James K. Polk, a strong territorial expansionist, won the
presidency in November 1844. Tyler,
knowing the Senate would not ratify the annexation treaty, changed
course and
had his allies in Congress submit an annexation bill of Texas
as a territory in a joint resolution in
December. With President-elect Polk’s quiet support, Congress approved
annexation of Texas as a
territory on February 28, 1845,
even though the Republic of Texas
had been recognized by the US
as an independent state since 1843. The March , 1845 vote on the joint
resolution in the Senate was passed 27 to 25. Tyler
signed the Joint Resolution into law, which called for annexation of Texas
to be concluded by the end of December 1845. On December 29, 1845, President Polk
approved Texas’s
admission to the Union not as a territory but
as a
state. However, as this was done via a Joint Resolution of Congress,
rather
than a treaty between states, some scholars believe the annexation is
unconstitutional
and illegal under international law.
A factor in the Texas
annexation discussions in the US
the northern states realized that there would be two new slave state
Senators after Texas
was admitted as a state.
Although Mexico
had outlawed slavery completely years prior to Texas
independence, slavery was allowed to continue in Mexican Texas, and
continued
to exist in Texas during
its
years as an independent Republic.
Mexico
broke off diplomatic relations with the U.S.
in 1845 over the issue, which eventually led to the Mexican-America War
the
following year. The Treaty of Guadalupe Hidalgo ended the war when the
victorious U.S.
ratified
the treaty on March 10, 1848.
The treaty allowed the U.S.
to purchase California
and other
areas from Mexico
on the condition that Americans would honor Mexican culture and values,
a
condition US
settler promptly ignored. The annexation of Texas
was highly controversial amongst the states and contributed to widening
American sectionalism leading up to the Civil War. Later, Manifest
Destiny
served as moral justification for US imperialist expansion into Central
America and the Pacific during the Age of Imperialism.
Nineteenth-century Prussia
viewed its destiny as the unification of the German people into a
modern nation
state to overcome tribal rivalry encouraged by foreign interference. Bismarck
exploited German nationalism that had been frustrated by the failure of
the
Revolutions of 1848 to unify a fragmented Germany
in 1871 to build a German Empire to rival that of Britain.
British national destiny under Queen Victoria
from 1837was to transform an island kingdom into a global empire that
would
last for more than a century until 1947. The destiny of the France
under Louis XIV in 1643 was to forge a powerful nation state out of
medieval
feudalism. The destiny of Napoleonic France in 1769 was the
construction of a
multinational continental world order under French cultural and
political leadership
based on the ideals of the French Revolution.
The destiny of the Ottoman dominion during the 15th
and 16th centuries was to maintain peace in a multi-ethnic
world
under the aegis of Islam. The destiny of the Holy Roman
Empire
in 962 AD was to establish and maintain a Christian political order in Europe
under an elected Holy Roman Emperor. The destiny of Qin dynasty China
in 221 BCE was to forge a unified Chinese nation.
The national destiny of modern China
since the beginning of the 20th century has been the
restoration of China
to its rightful historical position in the modern world order. Up until
the Age
of Western Imperialism which spanned from mid 19th century
to mid 20th
century, China
had been a continuous cultural fountainhead and economic dynamo
throughout its
recorded history of four millennia without taking on the belligerent
hubris of
a modern superpower. Today, New China has steadfastly declared that it
will
never assume the aggressive role of a superpower. New China
aims to spread the Chinese vision of an equitable world order not by
force of
arms, but by example of its commitment to build an equitable harmonious
society
within its borders and in a world order. The national destiny of New
China is
inseparable from China’s
socialist root to protect and develop the common interest of working
people even
in feudal dynastic days and from which it has derived invincible
strength to
defeat Western imperialism.
Chinese political culture is based on the principle of Great
Harmony (Da Tong) in which individualism, both personal and
institutional, is
subordinate to community as a natural order. This natural order has
been derived
from four millennia of a living philosophical tradition in a nation
with continuously
functioning political-cultural institutions, as the geo-cultural,
multi-ethnic
center of the known world. Western capitalist democracy based on
individualism
is antithetical to Chinese socio-political culture. Mercantile values
have not
been highly placed in Chinese culture and society. Historically, over a
period
of four millennium, every time China
deviated from this socialist tradition, the nation ended in decline.
Today, China
is a modern nation state with one fifth of the world’s population and
the
longest continuous civilization and history. This is why China
continues to refer to herself culturally as Zhong
Hua, which means Centric Civilization of Opulence, and politically
as Zhong Guo, meaning Centric Nation State.
Modern China,
organized politically as a communist nation in the hay day of Western
capitalism, is a fusion of traditional Chinese communal political
culture and
Western dialectic materialism.
Mao Zedong, the greatest revolutionary leader in modern
Chinese history, wrote in his 1937 essay On
Contradiction:
According
to materialist
dialectics, changes in nature are due chiefly to the development of
internal contradictions.
Changes in society are due chiefly to the development of the internal
contradictions
in society, that is, contradiction between productive forces and the
relations
of production, contradiction between classes and contradiction between
old and new.
It is the development of these contradictions that pushes society
forward and
gives the impetus for the supersedure of old society by new.
Does materialist
dialectics exclude external
causes? Not at all. It
holds that external causes are the condition of change and internal
causes are
the basis of change, and that external causes become operative through
internal
causes. In a suitable temperature an egg changes into a chicken, but no
temperature can change a stone into a chicken, because each has a
different
basis.
There is constant
interaction between the
people of different countries.
In the era of capitalism, and especially in the era of imperialism and
proletarian revolution, the interaction and mutual impact of different
countries in the political, economic and cultural spheres are extremely
great.
The October Socialist
Revolution ushered in a
new epoch in world history
as well as in Russian history. It exerted influence on internal changes
in the
other countries in the world and, similarly and in a particularly
profound way,
on internal changes in China.
These changes, however, were effected through the inner laws of
development of
these countries, China included.
In battle, one army is victorious and the
other is defeated; both the
victory and the defeat are determined by internal causes. The one is
victorious
either because it is strong or because of its competent generalship,
the other
is vanquished either because it is weak or be cause of its incompetent
generalship; it is through internal causes that external causes become
operative.
In China in 1927, the defeat of the
proletariat by the big bourgeoisie
came about through the opportunism then to be found within the Chinese
proletariat itself (inside the Chinese Communist Party). When we
liquidated
this opportunism, the Chinese revolution resumed its advance. Later,
the
Chinese revolution again suffered severe setbacks at the hands of the
enemy,
because adventurism had risen within our Party. When we liquidated this
adventurism, our cause advanced once again. Thus it can be seen that to
lead
the revolution to victory, a political party must depend on the
correctness of
its own political line and the solidity of its own organization.
Mao correctly predicted the fall of the Soviet Union
as the inevitable outcome of the revisionism of Communist
Party of the Soviet Union.
The current global financial crisis that began in August
2007 is a manifestation of the internal contradiction of the
dysfunctional
globalized capitalist free market fundamentalism. On this “external
cause” of global
financial crisis, the Chinese Communist Party will be well advised to
heed Chairman
Mao’s warning about the importance of the correctness of its own
political line
to respond to China’s “inner laws of development” in the context of
external structural
changes in the rest of the world.
Mao continued on the history of dialectics:
The dialectical
world outlook
emerged in ancient times both in China
and in Europe. Ancient dialectics, however, had
a
somewhat spontaneous and naive character; in the social and historical
conditions then prevailing, it was not yet able to form a theoretical
system,
hence it could not fully explain the world and was supplanted by
metaphysics.
The celebrated German
philosopher
Hegel, who lived in the late 18th and early 19th centuries, made
important
contributions to dialectics, but his dialectics was idealist. It was
not until
Marx and Engels, the great protagonists of the proletarian movement,
had
synthesized the positive achievements in the history of human knowledge
and, in
particular, critically absorbed the rational elements of Hegelian
dialectics
and created the great theory of dialectical and historical materialism
that an
unprecedented revolution occurred in the history of human knowledge.
This
theory was further developed by Lenin and Stalin. As soon as it spread
to China,
it wrought tremendous changes in the world of Chinese thought.
Modern Chinese thought has been impacted by Marxism because,
as Mao observed, external causes in the form of Western imperialism in China
are the “conditions of change” and internal causes of China’s
own decay are the “basis of change”. The external causes have become
operative
through internal causes. Marxism, which
insightfully identifies the causes of Western imperialism, is the world
view
with which China
struggles against Western imperialism. Classical Chinese thought did
not
deal
with Western imperialism because Western imperialism did not exist
before the
mid 19th century in China,
and had been out of the realm of discourse in Chinese thought.
On contradiction, Mao wrote:
The
fundamental contradiction in the process of development of a thing and
the
essence of the process determined by this fundamental contradiction
will not
disappear until the process is completed; but in a lengthy process the
conditions usually differ at each stage. The reason is that, although
the
nature of the fundamental contradiction in the process of development
of a
thing and the essence of the process remain unchanged, the fundamental
contradiction becomes more and more intensified as it passes from one
stage to
another in the lengthy process.
In addition, among the numerous major and
minor contradictions which are
determined or influenced by the fundamental contradiction, some become
intensified, some are temporarily or partially resolved or mitigated,
and some
new ones emerge; hence the process is marked by stages. If people do
not pay
attention to the stages in the process of development of a thing, they
cannot
deal with its contradictions properly.
The conditions in the lengthy process of “fundamental
contradiction between productive forces and the relations of
production, contradiction
between classes and contradiction between old and new” have
irreversibly
changed since August 2007. Market capitalism has at long last
undeniably revealed
its structural internal contradiction. The world is at the threshold of
a new
economic order based on constructive cooperation rather than the
senseless
competition promoted by neoliberal capitalistic market fundamentalism.
Unless China
pays attention to this “stage” in the process of development of its
national
destiny and national interest, it cannot deal with the contradictions
properly.
Joseph Schumpeter (1883- 1950), whose “creative destruction”
notion was tirelessly misquoted by Alan Greenspan, the US central
banker
primarily responsible for the global debt bubble, to support the myth
of perpetually
self-renewal capitalism through financial manipulation, wrote about the
inevitable end of capitalism in his History of Economic Analysis.
Capitalism,
Socialism and Democracy, first published during World War II in
1942. In Chapter 11: The civilization of capitalism,
Schumpeter observed that capitalism grew out of a social trend to
rationalize economic
activity, the acceptance of which reinforced amoral rationalism by
condoning,
as legitimate natural instinct, the single-minded seeking of individual
self-interest through empirical “scientific” modeling, such as
simplistic quantification
of quality, single-dimensional efficiency calculation, disconnected
cost-benefit
analysis, synthetic trade-off decision-making, and shallow positivism
in place
of profound metaphysics.
Rationality naturally challenges traditional feudal values
and institutions and would eventually undermine also bourgeois values
and
institutions of capitalism. Rationality will destabilize the
intellectual legitimacy
of capitalism itself by making entrepreneurship superfluous, replacing
it with
corporate planning, organized research and monopolistic predation.
Corporatism
thrives on giantism at the expense of individual entrepreneurship.
Successful
entrepreneurs will inevitably be incorporated or be acquired by
corporations through
consolidation inherent in finance capitalism. To curb this tendency,
anti-trust
regulatory regimes are necessary.
Schumpeter observes further that progress of capitalism
reduces the importance of small producers and traders, the so-called
small and
medium enterprises, and thereby erodes the fundamental meaning of
“property”
and the sanctity of “contract”, since property belonging to a giant
corporation
and contracts entered into with such a corporation are collective
undertakings.
“This evaporation of what we may term the material substance of
property - its
visible and touchable reality - affects not only the attitude of
holders but
also that of the workmen and of the public in general. Dematerialized,
de-functionalized
and absentee ownership does not impress and call forth moral allegiance
as the
vital form of property did,” Schumpeter wrote. Company assets are not
viewed
with the same proprietary interest by society as personal assets by
individuals. Corporatism is a special exclusionary form of
collectivism. To
purge corporatism of its socialist content, market capitalism creates a
legal
regime to treat corporations as legal individuals.
Schumpeter saw intellectuals as constituting a group “whose
interest it is to work up and organize [social] resentment, to nurse
it, to
voice it and to lead it” against bourgeois institutions weakened by
collective
developments. To Schumpeter, intellectuals are “people who wield the
power of the
spoken and the written word” in the “absence of direct responsibility
for
practical affairs.” Intellectuals assert
themselves by their “actual or potential nuisance value.” Intellectuals
are
true revolutionaries. Those in the employ of government or business
cease to be
intellectuals to become policy strategists for specific missions. This
revolutionary function of intellectual should not be confused with the
army of
opportunist dissidents promoted and supported by Western bourgeois
interests to
destabilized socialist governments.
Capitalism encouraged the growth and activity of the
intellectual class by providing it with support from the collective
patron, the
bourgeois public. The bourgeoisie will try to curb intellectual
criticism of
capitalism, but is prevented from effective persecution of this effort.
If a
bourgeois government tries to curb criticism from intellectuals, “the
bourgeois
stratum, however strongly disapproving some of their doings, will rally
behind
them because the freedom it disapproves cannot be crushed without also
crushing
the freedom it approves... In defending the intellectuals as a group -
not of
course every individual - the bourgeoisie defends itself and its scheme
of life.”
The bourgeois social atmosphere will drive public policy more and more
hostile
towards capitalism.
Schumpeter concluded that the capitalist process not only
destroys its own institutional framework but it also creates the
conditions for
its eventual replacement. The outcome of the process is that individual
hearts
and minds are transformed to become increasingly amenable to the
collective
form of life, what sociologist and Fortune Magazine editor William H. Whyte (1917-1999) called
the Organization Man.
Whyte explained that “the corporation man is the most
conspicuous example, but he is only one, for the collectivization so
visible in
the corporation has affected almost every field of work. Blood brother
to the
business trainee off to join Du Pont is the seminary student who win
end up in
the church hierarchy, the doctor headed for the corporate clinic, the
physics
Ph.D. in a government laboratory, the intellectual on the
foundation-sponsored
team project, the engineering graduate in the huge drafting room at
Lockheed,
the young apprentice in a Wall Street law factory.”
The organizations these organization men perpetuate are so
interconnected that they are all “too big to fail” which is the point
when corporate
capitalism transforms into corporate socialism with the help of the
state. To
Schumpeter, Marx’s vision of socialism replacing capitalism
was correct.
Reaching his personal maturity in the 1930s, Schumpeter saw with
apprehension that
capitalism would use national socialism as a antibiotic against
proletariat socialism.
Schumpeter outlined the “socialist blueprint” in which
central planning can use markets as a mechanism for feed back to
validate
profit-oriented publicly-owned means of production for the benefit of
society.
Since profit depends of consumer power, there would be structural
incentive on
the part of management to raise wages to increase sales. A market
economy can
exist whether the means of production are privately or collectively
owned, but only
under socialism will profit be socialized to support consumer power,
rather
than be corporatized to profit shareholders.
Mao wrote further:
For instance, when
the capitalism of the era of free competition developed into
imperialism, there
was no change in the class nature of the two classes in fundamental
contradiction, namely, the proletariat and the bourgeoisie, or in the
capitalist essence of society; however, the contradiction between these
two
classes became intensified, the contradiction between monopoly and
non-monopoly
capital emerged, the contradiction between the colonial powers and the
colonies
became intensified, the contradiction among the capitalist countries
resulting
from their uneven development manifested itself with particular
sharpness, and
thus there arose the special stage of capitalism, the stage of
imperialism.
Leninism is the Marxism of the era of
imperialism and proletarian
revolution precisely because Lenin and Stalin have correctly explained
these
contradictions and correctly formulated the theory and tactics of the
proletarian revolution for their resolution.
Take the
process of China’s
bourgeois-democratic revolution, which began with the Revolution of
1911; it,
too, has several distinct stages. In particular, the revolution in its
period
of bourgeois leadership and the revolution in its period of proletarian
leadership represent two vastly different historical stages. In other
words,
proletarian leadership has fundamentally changed the whole face of the
revolution,
has brought about a new alignment of classes, given rise to a
tremendous
upsurge in the peasant revolution, imparted thoroughness to the
revolution
against imperialism and feudalism, created the possibility of the
transition
from the democratic revolution to the socialist revolution, and so on.
None of these
was possible in the period when the revolution was under bourgeois
leadership.
Although no change has taken place in the nature of the fundamental
contradiction in the process as a whole, i.e., in the
anti-imperialist, anti-feudal, democratic-revolutionary nature of the
process
(the opposite of which is its semi-colonial and semi-feudal nature),
nonetheless this process has passed through several stages of
development in
the course of more than twenty years.
During this
time many great events have taken place -- the failure of the
Revolution of
1911 and the establishment of the regime of the Northern warlords, the
formation of the first national united front and the revolution of
1924-27, the
break-up of the united front and the desertion of the bourgeoisie to
the side
of the counter revolution, the wars among the new warlords, the
Agrarian
Revolutionary War, the establishment of the second national united
front and
the War of Resistance Against Japanese Imperialism.
These stages
are marked by particular features such as the intensification of
certain
contradictions (e.g., the Agrarian Revolutionary War and
the
Japanese invasion of the four northeastern provinces), the partial or
temporary
resolution of other contradictions (e.g., the destruction
of the
Northern warlords and our confiscation of the land of the landlords),
and the
emergence of yet other contradictions (e.g., the
conflicts among
the new warlords, and the landlords' recapture of the land after the
loss of
our revolutionary base areas in the south).
Today, when capitalist market fundamentalism is facing a
structural crisis from the adverse effect of debt preempting capital, a
fundamental issue is whether socialist China, whose national destiny is
inseparably tied to socio-economic revolution towards an equitable
society and a
just world order, should allow itself to be lured into the role of a
“stakeholder”
in the collapsing neo-liberal capitalist world order of financial
neo-imperialism.
National Destiny and
National Interest
A nation’s destiny determines its national interest at a
specific time in history. China’s
national interest in the 21st century is focused on
national resurgence
through socio-economic redevelopment along the path of its historical
socio-cultural tradition of harmonious socialism. The purpose of
redevelopment
is to maintain socio-economic growth by increasing the national wealth
to
support the continuing advancement of Chinese civilization which in
turn
contributes to the advancement of world civilization.
National Wealth
The national wealth is the sum total of all wealth within a
nation. All economic systems, feudal, capitalist or socialist, strive
to increase
national wealth. The national wealth is affected by a nation’s system
and
pattern of ownership and its distributional configuration, defined by
the ratio
between collective ownership of the means of production and the private
sector
based on individual private property rights.
Wealth is defined by Webster’s Dictionary as a large
aggregate of real and personal property; an abundance of those material
or
worldly things that people desire to possess; riches; also the state of
being
rich. That state is derived from abundance. The national wealth
includes state
property and individual property. The net benefits of wealth lie in its
consumption.
Security is provided by surplus wealth that can be consumed at a future
date.
However, a surplus of wealth is not synonymous with a wealth of
surplus; it is
in fact the opposite. The former is economically unproductive while the
latter
can facilitate qualitative growth. Surplus wealth is by definition
economically
inert. A wealth of surplus can advance civilization to a higher plane.
In measuring a civilization, focus is placed on wealth of
tradition, of culture, of creativity, of morality, of social justice,
of
knowledge, of expertise, of spirit, of compassion, and so on. Value
placed on
non-material assets is indicative of the state of advancement in a
civilization. Highly developed civilizations move from high valuation
of
materialistic wellbeing to higher valuation of spiritual wellbeing.
The Greeks glorified beauty and the Romans worshiped power. Greek
civilization enriched humanity with a wealth of philosophy based on
aesthetics while
Roman civilization gave the Western world a wealth of laws based on
order.
Christ taught the Christian world to love the poor and the weak and to
celebrate
only the spiritual wealth of the meek. Early Christians were the first
socialists. Chinese civilization is built around the family of men as
brothers.
Chinese political culture operates on the vision of community from
which the
individual cannot detach without damaging his/her humanity. It does not
recognize the Western notion of the economic man operating out of self
interest
which Chinese culture views as deviant behavior.
In classical economics, wealth is an abundance of all
material objects which have economic utility in a world of natural
scarcity. Wealth then presupposes
inequality. Neoclassical
economics introduces the concept that scarcity enhances the marginal
utility of
wealth. In neoclassical economics, scarcity of a commodity enhances its
exchange
value while aggregate scarcity depresses wealth. Scarcity is a
necessary
condition for a functioning market. Abundance denies the necessity for
trade.
In a knowledge scarce economy, knowledge is wealth and in an
information scarce economy, information is wealth, even though
knowledge
overkill and information overload are frequent problems that can cause
economic
stagnation. Thus abundance alone does not solve the problem of
scarcity, the
solution for which can only come from fair distribution. Scarcity
cannot be
eliminated by wealth creation alone since wealth is a function of
selective
scarcity. Scarcity can only be eliminated by equitable wealth
distribution. Therein lies the
structural dilemma of capitalism which depends on scarcity to create
wealth.
Currency hegemony distorts distributional equity in trade. Under
dollar hegemony, the distribution of the benefits of trade is distorted
mainly
because dollar is scarce in all trading economies except the US
which can produce dollars at will by fiat. Dollar hegemony emerges when
the US
discover how to transfer the cost of fiat dollar creation to her
trading
partners. This dollar-based international finance architecture allows
the US
to become the world’s largest debtor nation by assuming debts
denominated in
dollar that the US
can produce endlessly at no cost to itself. The cost of dollar
depreciation
from oversupply is transferred to foreign holders of dollars. The
question is
seldom asked why a country that can produces dollars at will needs to
borrow
dollars from its trade partners. The answer is of course that the US
borrows not out of its need for dollars, but to reinforce the need for
dollars
on the part of her trading partners. This dollar-denominated debt owed
by the US
to her trade partners is a debt the US
never has to pay back, or if forced to do so, the US
can pay this debt with more dollars she can print at will.
In economics, annual gross national product (GNP), a measure
of goods and services in the nation in a year, adjusted by foreign
factor
income, has been the generally accepted indicator of the economic
potential of
a nation. GNP is not a measure of the national wealth, which is the sum
total
of net assets of a nation. But GNP is only a measure of the monetized
wealth
derived from the national asset for a given time frame, not the asset
itself. A
low GNP can result form a large national asset, which is the definition
of
underdevelopment. All developing national economies, including that of China,
can raise their GNP by fulfilling the productive potential of their
national
assets.
The predominant asset of a nation is its population.
All secular wealth is derived from human life. Even on a personal level, when life ends, all
else secular, including wealth, ends for that individual, even hope,
which is the
wealth of future potential. Material wealth is a poor compensation for
poor
health. From this one can logically
deduce that national wealth is based fundamentally on a healthy and
fulfilled population. Without population,
there is no nation, let
alone national wealth. When the
population of a nation increases, so does its national asset and
potential national
wealth, unless the economic system is dysfunctional, in which case the
fault is
not with population growth, but with the economic system.
The physical, mental, intellectual, cultural
and spiritual health of the population in a social context has a direct
and
fundamental impact on the national wealth.
Cēterīs paribus (all else
equal), China
with one fifth of the world’s population should have a GNP equaling to
one
fifth of world 2007 GDP of $54.6 trillion, or $11 trillion instead of
$3.3
trillion. China’s
2007 GDP was below its asset potential by a factor of three by world
average
standard. By advanced economy standard, China’s
GDP should be five time that of the US
($14.5 trillion in 2008), or $72,5 trillion. Yet China holds a foreign
exchange
reserve of $2 trillion, about 60% of which is in the form of US
sovereign and
agency debt. The US,
with the world largest GDP economy, and the world largest debtor
nation, has no
foreign debt denominated in foreign currency. All debts owed by the US
to foreigners are US sovereign debts denominated in dollars, not
foreign debts
denominated in foreign currencies.
If China, with a population five times that of the US, had
the same productivity as the US, its population would produce five
times the US
2007 GDP of $13.8 trillion. China
would have a GDP of $59 trillion instead of $3.3 trillion in 2007. China’s
2007 GDP would have been bigger than world GDP in stead of one third of
it. China
ranked 100th in world per capita GDP in 2007 ($ 5,400 - half
of
world per capita GDP of $10,038), behind Swaziland
(99th) and Samoa (98th).
The Scarcity Dogma
Neoclassical economics subscribes religiously to the dogma
of scarcity as a natural law of economic science to underpin the law of
supply
and demand. The dogma states that given
an amount of demand, scarcity causes prices to rise. Thus there is
structural
incentive to maintain or even increase scarcity. Prices are allowed to
fall
only if aggregate sale increases. Scarcity, however, is never allowed
to
disappear entirely, at which point markets would stop functioning.
When clean air and water were abundant, instead of
constructing an economic theory from these happy natural gifts of
nature,
economists reject them as non-commodities, external to the concern of
economics, until of course clean air and water became scarce through
pollution
or simply abusive use, then and only then would scarcity make clean air
and
water legitimate economic issues.
Scarcity Theory and
Population Control
Similarly, population growth in a world of scarcity is
considered a rising burden to the economic system.
These economists, of whom Thomas Robert
Malthus being the spokesman, argue for the need of population control
based on
the dogma of scarcity.
Malthus (1766-1834), British economist, sociologist and
pioneer in population theory, in his An
Essay on the Principle of Population (1798), contends that poverty
is
unavoidable without population control since scarcity is a condition
that
naturally increases with population growth. Famine
and disease are natural constraints on
population growth and war
is a socio-political constraint. In
1803, Malthus conceded the preventive check of “moral restraint”,
paving the
way for neo-Malthusian birth control theories which influenced
classical
economists, especially David Ricardo (1772-1823). Birth
control is then viewed as a moral
alternative to famine and war.
But as history has since borne out, global food production
growth has long outstripped global population growth. The biggest
problem in
modern agricultural economics is not excessive demand but falling
prices caused
by over-production. As to the causes of
war, advanced countries of low birth rate frequently invade developing
countries with high birth rate all through history.
Many advanced economies, such as those of France
and Japan,
have
found it necessary to adopt incentive policies to stimulate population
growth
in order to maintain economic growth and national power.
Ricardo’s interest in economics was sparked by Adam Smith's Wealth
of Nations (1776). Smith's thesis
was that the division of labor (specialization) improves economic
growth to
generate wealth for all nations. Smith also saw advancements
in
machination and international trade as engines of growth through the
facilitation of further specialization. Because savings by the rich is
what
provides investment and hence economic growth, Ricardo saw unequal
income
distribution as being one of the most important determinants of
national
economic growth. However, Ricardo posited that savings is in part
determined by
the profits of stock: as the capital stock of a competition between
capitalists
for workers will bid wages up to reduce profit. So lowering the living
standards of workers was another way to maintain or accelerate economic
growth. Free markets cannot include free
labor markets that enhance worker market power if economic growth is to
be maintained.
Ricardo provided the “scientific” rationale for the
anti-labor mentality of capitalism. Capital
is deployed to enhance labor
productivity not to raise the
standard of living of workers, but to increase return on capital. Wage
increases
tie to increased labor productivity directly decease the productivity
of
capital. Mechanization is a process to shrink labor input per unit of
capital
investment, not to raise the cost of labor.
Wage increase can be tolerated only if aggregate wage falls.
Lay off one hundred workers and use the wages of 20 displaced workers
to fund
wage increases of the remaining workers who are expected to cover the
productivity of the hundred laid-off workers. Most of the growth of the
industrial age came from robbing labor of it fair share by keeping
demand for
labor shrinking with investment in capital goods. Surplus labor reduces
the
market power of labor while it magnifies the market power of capital.
Capitalists fear full employment more than they fear the plague.
This is why economies operating under market capitalism,
including that of China,
will be structurally prevented from achieving full employment with high
wages.
For an economy that depends of foreign investment, even surplus profits
do not
stay within the economy.
Ricardo’s law of rent was seminally influenced by Malthusian
concepts on population. Malthus claimed
that population growth is not easily checked and would quickly outstrip
economic growth and cause increasing misery all around.
Accepting that, Ricardo modified Smith’s
theory of economic growth by including diminishing returns on land.
Output
growth requires growth of factor inputs, which are goods and services
used in
the process of production, such as land, labor, capital and enterprise. But unlike labor, land is “variable in
quality and fixed in supply”. This means that as economic growth
proceeds, more land must be brought into use. But land cannot be
increased
without conquest, which led economic growth inevitably to the age of
imperialism and empire. Prior to that imperialist stage, there
were two
self-neutralizing effects from economic growth: firstly, rising
landowner
rents over time cut into the profits of capitalists from above;
secondly,
rising price of wage goods over time cuts into profits from below as
workers
need higher wages for subsistence. This introduces a quicker limit to
economic
growth than Smith allowed, but Ricardo also claimed that this decline
can be
happily checked by technological improvements in machinery and the
specialization brought by trade. Wage arbitrage has always been a
key
factor in international trade.
However, in the third edition of his Principles,
Ricardo modified his position on mechanization, observing that when
mechanization
displaces labor, the labor thus “set free” may not be reabsorbed
elsewhere in
the economy because capital is not simultaneously “set free”. This creates downward pressure on wages and
lowers aggregate labor income, with the difference absorbed by the high
investment
cost of capital goods. It is true that capital goods also require
labor
to produce, but the productive lifespan of capital goods after their
initial
labor input is very long, which brings about the need for finance. Capital goods need decades of reduced labor
cost to pay for them and their financing cost, i.e. interest, requires
additional reduced labor cost to service over the life span of the
financing.
In order to reabsorb labor displaced by mechanization, the
rate of capital accumulation must continuously increase. But
there is no
obvious mechanism for this to happen -- particularly given the tendency
for
profits and thus savings to decline over time from over investment. In a high tech economy, which Ricardo did not
have the opportunity to observe in his life time, technological
obsolescence
tends to require an even higher and more frequently recurring level of
mental
labor input, rescuing high-tech workers from Ricardo’s Iron Law of
Wages. The wage differential then fall
even more
heavily on production workers.
Ricardo did not deal with the problem of uneven market
demand on different grades of labor created by mechanization, between
educated
scientists/engineers creative workers and factory production workers. Until the introduction of universal
education, a non-market social program, unskilled or low-skilled labor
simply
could not afford education for their children, thus condemning them to
the
ranks of the unemployable for life generation after generation. This
created a
shortage of educated workers and an oversupply of unskilled labor,
resulting in
drastic income disparity. As income rise
comes to depend on education level, the cost of education also requires
financing over longer periods of schooling and more sophisticated
teaching and
research facilities and institutions, limiting access by the poor. The unequal access to education is the
fundamental factor behind the rise of a class society.
To Ricardo, rent is a result and not a cause of price.
Rent has two different meanings
for economists. The first is the commonplace definition: the income
from
hiring out an asset, such as money, land or other durable goods. The
second,
known as economic rent, is a measure of market power: the difference
between
what a factor of production costs and how much it would need to be paid
to
remain in its current use. A star entertainer may be paid $10 million a
year
when he/she would be willing to perform for only $1 million under
different
circumstances, so his economic rent is $9 million a year. In perfect
competition, there are no economic rents, as new entertainers are
attracted by
a high rent market and compete until economic rent falls to near zero.
Reducing
rent does not change production decisions, so economic rent can be
taxed to
reduce income disparity without any adverse impact on the real economy.
Upon these concepts, Ricardo propounded his iron law of
wages and a labor theory of value. The
iron law of wages asserts that wages naturally drift towards minimum
levels and
cannot rise above subsistence levels. The
theory of value maintains that in
exchange, the value, though not
the market price, of goods is measured by the amount of labor expended
in their
production. When the market price
differs from value, it causes either inflation or deflation, producing
drags on
economic growth. Central banking was then invented to maintain price
stability
via monetary elasticity and to control wage rises through unemployment.
The national wealth of China
is dragged down by low wages. All economic and development policies
should be
focused on raising wages as a primary objective. On recent decades,
foreign
direct investment has reinforced the Ricardo Iron Law of Wages on the
Chinese
economy through its dependence of export. The Chinese export sector
competes on
its advantage in cross-border wage arbitrage. This strategy depresses
Chinese
national wealth. Until China
realizes that export based on low wages is a self-diminishing strategy,
Chinese
national wealth will remain underdeveloped no matter how much foreign
exchange
reserves in holds. National income denominated in a nation’s own
currency is
the only way to increase national wealth. And for a large population
country
such as China,
wages are the main source of national income.
On interest, Ricardo had little to say. He observed that
money, by which he meant gold-back specie money, not fiat money, “is
subject to
incessant variations from its being a commodity obtained from a foreign
country, from its being the general medium of exchange between all
civilized
countries, and from its being also distributed among those countries in
proportions which are ever changing with every improvement in commerce
and
machinery, and with every increasing difficulty of obtaining food and
necessaries for an increasing population. In stating the principles
which
regulate exchangeable value and price, we should carefully distinguish
between
those variations which belong to the commodity itself, and those which
are
occasioned by a variation in the medium in which value is estimated, or
price
expressed.”
Ricardo asserted that a rise in wages due to inflation
produces no real effect on profits, known in modern times as cost of
living
increases or indexation, as prices of products also rise.
A rise in real wages ahead of inflation has a
direct effect in lowering profits. Labor, when purchased and sold as a
commodity, may increase or diminish quantitatively in supply and has a
natural
price and a market price. The natural price of labor is that price
which is
necessary to enable laborers to subsist and “to perpetuate their race
without
either increase or diminution.”
But there is nothing “natural” about Ricardo’s natural price
of labor. What Ricardo called natural was actually an artificial
socio-political regime. In that regime,
as then existed in England,
population grew naturally without intervention and the growth tended to
be
concentrated on the laboring poor who had the least capacity to
intervene on
their fate in society. Ricardo’s natural
price of labor depends on the price of the food, necessaries, and
conveniences
required for the subsistent support of the laborer and his family.
Ricardo’s
iron law of wages is derived from his view that population is a
liability
rather than an asset to the economy. The lower wages fall without
starving
workers to death, the higher the profit capital can realize to produce
a rich
economy.
Yet over-investment will lead to overcapacity unless wages
rise to sustain more consumption. To solve this problem of insufficient
demand,
neoclassical economics resorted to foreign trade to earn gold to enrich
the
nation. In the 21st century, emerging economies, led by China,
have been seduced into dependence on export. But under dollar hegemony,
the
exporting economies do not earn gold or even gold-backed money. The
earn
dollars which cannot be used in the domestic economies without first
converting
the dollars back into local currencies. This however will cause
inflation
because the wealth behind this local currency has been shipped to
foreign
markets for dollars. The emerging economies cannot shift towards
domestic
consumption because domestic wages have been kept too low and the
profit from
low wages has gone to foreign capital denominated in dollars.
In a functioning economy, the natural price of labor should
be based workers being able to purchase the goods their labor produces.
It
should also be based on society’s concept of a good life, which
includes good
provision for family, ample leisure to cultivate the body and spirit,
occupational safety, health care, continuing education, affordable
housing and dignified
retirement benefits. Subsistence has
taken on different, more equitable and humane meanings since the early
days of
the Industrial Revolution. Ricardo
granted that with technological and social progress, the natural price
of labor
always has a tendency to rise, while the natural price of commodities,
excepting raw material and labor, has a tendency to fall because of
innovation
that improves productivity.
When the market price of labor is determined by supply and
demand, unemployment is needed to depress the market price of labor.
This can only
be achieved by increasing labor supply to saturate labor demand. When the market price of labor exceeds its
natural price, the condition of the laborer is flourishing and happy.
By the
encouragement which high wages give to the increase of population, the
number
of laborers will increase and wages will again fall to their natural
price
level, and indeed from a overshoot reaction sometimes fall below it. So goes the argument for population control
for
the good of the laboring class, or as Ricardo put it, “the laboring
race.” The Christian Church, having for
most of its
history allied itself with establishment interests, opposes birth
control in
modern time for more than religious and moral reasons.
When the market price of labor is below its natural price,
the condition of the laborers is wretched and poverty results. It is only after their privations have
reduced population increase, or the demand for labor has increased
through
economic growth, that the market price of labor can be raised to its
natural
price, and that the laborer will have the moderate comforts which the
natural
rate of wages will afford. Notwithstanding
the tendency of wages to
conform to their natural rate,
their market rate may be constantly above it in an improving and
progressive
society for an indefinite period. Thus,
with every improvement of society, with every increase in capital, the
market
wages of labor will rise; but the permanence of their rise will depend
on whether
the natural price of labor has also risen; and this again will depend
on the
rise in the natural price of those necessaries on which the wages of
labor are
expended.
As population increases, these necessaries will be
constantly rising in price, because more labor will be necessary to
produce
them and more people are consuming them. If
the money wages of labor should fall, while
every commodity on which
the wages of labor were expended rose, workers would be doubly
affected, and
would be soon totally deprived of subsistence. Instead
of the money wages of labor falling,
they would rise; but they
would not rise sufficiently to enable the laborer to purchase as many
comforts
and necessaries as he did before the rise in the price of those
commodities. Ricardo concluded that
these are the iron laws by which wages are regulated, and by which the
happiness of far the greatest part of every community is governed.
Labor then
has a self interest in assuring the profitability of employers. This has been a self-regulating attitude
since adopted by the labor union movement, putting labor at a constant
disadvantage in contract negotiations.
Thus according to Ricardo, emerging economies with an
underdeveloped labor force such as China can not expect to escape
incomes
disparity because capital formation depends on keeping workers poor.
Unless and until policymakers in China
realize that labor is not a commodity and that a labor market should
not exist
any more than a slave market should exist, China
will not achieve its destiny of restoring its proper place in the
world. To
fulfill China’s
national destiny, population must be viewed as asset, not a liability,
and labor
must not be viewed as a commodity and that capital exists to enhance
labor
productivity, not to buy labor at the cheaper possible price.
The real natural law is that capital needs labor more than
labor needs capital. Without capital,
labor can still produce, albeit less efficiently, but without labor,
capital
cannot exist and remains idle assets. The
market price of labor should always be such as to eliminate excess
profit for
capital; and labor has the power to command it, for capital has nowhere
else to
go. This is the point when government,
controlled by capital, steps in to break up strikes, to make
capitalists richer
at the expense of labor and at a lower level of national wealth.
Ricardo argued that like all other contracts, wages should
be left to the fair and free competition of the market, and should
never be
interfered with by government. He saw
the clear and direct tendency of the welfare laws and labor regulations
as in
direct opposition to these obvious principles: it is not, as social
legislation
benevolently intended, to amend the condition of the poor, but to
deteriorate
the condition of both poor and rich; instead of making the poor rich,
they are
calculated to make the rich poor, thus forfeiting savings and
investment needed
for economic growth. And while the
welfare laws are in force, the maintenance of the poor would
progressively
increase till it has absorbed all the net revenue of the nation. “This pernicious tendency of these laws is no
longer a mystery, since it has been fully developed by the able hand of
Mr.
Malthus; and every friend to the poor must ardently wish for their
abolition,”
Ricardo wrote. While this is rational
observation, Ricardo did not emphasize that the way to get out of the
welfare
trap is through full employment with living wages.
In Ricardo’s view, poverty is not the result
of the rich getting more than the poor, but the result of economic
underdevelopment due to lack of savings. This
has been the position adopted by most
market neoliberals.
Adam Smith (1723 - 1790), having come in contact with the
Physiocrats in France led by a physician to Louis XV, Francois Quesnay
(1694-1774), who believed that all wealth originates from land, wrote An Inquery into the Nature and Causes of the
Wealth of Nations in 1776, in which he postulated the theory of
division of
labor and observed that value, not price, arises from labor expended in
the
process of production.
The Physiocrat maxim states that only abundance combined
with high prices could create prosperity, a rejection of the theory of
price as
being set by the intersection of supply and demand in a free market. To the Pysiocrats, price theory based on
supply and demand causes abundance to drive down prices and leads to
producer
bankruptcies and economic depressions, preventing the sustenance of
abundance,
which is a requirement for prosperity.
This notion is behind the Keynesian idea of demand
management through high wages and full employment, even at the cost of
moderate
inflation. The most cited of Smith’s
ideas is the belief that in a laissez-faire
economy, the impulse of self interest would bring about the public
welfare. Yet
data have shown that unit maximization invariably leads to systemic
inefficiency. Individual interest unrestraint by societal values tends
to be
satisfied at the expense of community interests.
The most misunderstood of Smith’s ideas is the belief that
the term laissez-faire, which in
French means to leave alone, means
the absence of government interference in a free market economy. But Smith’s idea of a free domestic market is
one without monopolies, which he opposed as destroyers of free markets.
He also
opposed mercantilism in international trade, which aims to accumulate
gold
through monopolistic trade by active government policy.
Smith advocated strong government action to
restrict the inevitable emergence of monopolies in unregulated markets
domestically and mercantilism internationally. Smith
admitted restriction to free trade, such
as the Navigation Act of
1651, forbidding the importation of foreign goods and commodities from
overseas
colonies except in English-owned ships, as necessary national economic
defense
measures. In 1778, Smith was appointed
commissioner of customs for Scotland,
an ironic post for a free trader.
Smith in the Introduction to his Wealth of
Nations identifiedreal wealth as the annual produce of
the land and labor of the society. Henry
George (1839-97) virtually repeated the
single tax on land
argument of Victor de Mirabeau, Quesnay’s ardent disciple and father to
Honore
Mirabeau, popular revolutionary and statesman, spokesman for the Third
Estate.
“We must make land common property,” George declared.
Georgists identify three basic types of
property: common, government and private. Common
property belongs to all people in common; it is that which
all have an equal right to use and enjoy, such as public parks. Government property belongs to the
state and is subject to the direction of the government. Private
property is that which
individuals (or corporations as legal persons) have the exclusive right
to own,
profit from and dispose of as they see fit, subject to government
regulations.
Common property is not the same as government property. Common property
in the
ocean is generally recognized; the oceans do not belong to any one
government
beyond its costal economic zones. Common
property is different from private property in that common property
permits
private use, but implies an obligation to the community since the
rights of
others must be recognized. By its very
nature, land is common property and our laws and traditions already go
far
toward recognizing it as such. The principle of eminent domain asserts
the
superior claim of society to land. The New York State Constitution
states: “The
people of the State, in their right of sovereignty, possess the
original and
ultimate property in and to all lands within the jurisdiction of the
State.”
English and US laws generally recognize absolute ownership of goods -
but not
of land. The law deals with the land “owner” as a land holder - land is
held
under the sovereignty of the people and is subject to their conditions.
To preserve common property in land, George proposed that
the rent of land should be paid to the community. This payment
expresses the
exact amount that would satisfy the equal rights of all other members
of the
community. Individuals would retain title to land, fixity of tenure and
undisturbed possession. This method of making land “common property”
may also
be called “conditional private property in land” (payment of rent to
the
community) as opposed to “absolute private property in land” (private
collection of rent).
Adam Smith
(1723 - 1790) said: “Ground rents are a species of revenue which the
owner, in
many cases, enjoys without any care or attention of his own. Ground
rents are,
therefore, perhaps a species of revenue which can best bear to have a
peculiar
tax imposed upon them.” Tom
Paine (1737 - 1809) said: “Men did
not make the earth.... It is the value of the improvement only, and not
the
earth itself, that is individual property.... Every proprietor owes to
the
community a ground rent for the land which he holds.” Thomas
Jefferson (1743 - 1826) said: “The earth is given as a
common stock for men to labor and live on.” Half
a century later, Karl Marx (1818 - 1883)
said: “Assuming the
capitalist mode of production, then the capitalist is not only a
necessary
functionary but the dominating functionary in production. The landowner
on the
other hand is superfluous in this mode of production. If landed
property became
people’s property the whole basis of capitalist production would go.” John
Stuart Mill (1806 - 1873) said: “Landlords grow richer in their
sleep
without working, risking, or economizing. The increase in the value of
land,
arising as it does from the efforts of an entire community, should
belong to
the community and not to the individual who might hold title.” Abraham
Lincoln (1809 - 1865) said: “The land, the earth God gave man
for his
home, sustenance, and support, should never be the possession of any
man,
corporation, society, or unfriendly government, any more than the air
or
water....” Sun Yat-Sen
(1866 - 1925) said: “The land tax as the only means of
supporting the government is an infinitely just, reasonable, and
equitably
distributed tax, and on it we will found our new system.”
Wealth is a derivative of land value which in turn is a
derivative of the productivity of labor on it. Land value is a function
of
population density on land. Scarcely inhabited land has very low value,
except
for the value of the mineral or oil and gas under it.
Mao Zedong said that every person is capable of producing more than
he/she
consumes. When that does not happen, it
is the fault of the system, not the people. Mao Zedong said: “people
were the
most precious of all things.” Mao disputed the Malthusian argument that
food producers (capital) and consumers (population) burgeoning at
opposite poles of one and the same process as a phenomenon only in a
capitalist society. No explicit measures toward controlling
population expansion would be necessary in a communist society because
overpopulation was a result, not a cause, of poverty. Mao also believed
that China’s
population should expand in controlled fashion in accordance with a
planned
economy. Furthermore, prior to communist party rule, the population had
been kept
largely in check by a very high mortality rate. At times in China’s
history, increased reproduction was encouraged to provide an adequate
army and
tax base for the emperors.
The Chinese Communist Party (CCP) when it came into power in 1949
inherited
this high mortality rate and a population level fluctuating under the
scourge
of disease and malnutrition. A primary goal of the CCP since its
founding was
to improve the condition of the population, over 80% of which are rural
peasants. Population is the most valuable national asset. Economic
policy must
aim at maximizing the full potential of this national asset by ensuring
the
provision of food, housing, health care, education and employment for
all. A
socialist nation should not permit poverty anywhere within its borders,
more so
if income disparity contributes to the existence of poverty. China’s
poverty eradication record is not impressive in relation to its high
GDP
growth.
Today, China
has an export bubble, a real estate bubble, and a financial stock
market
bubble, but not an economic bubble. These
sector bubbles are the result of mal-distribution of resources directed
by flawed
development policy. An economy that still has large pockets of poverty
cannot
have an overall bubble.
There is urgent need for reform in China’s
three-decades-old economic reform and “open to the outside” policy.
Chinese
policymakers need to ask why consumers outside of China
can afford to buy Chinese goods while its own rural population cannot
afford to
do the same. The answer will show that poverty is always the result of
economic
policy. Any policy that fails to eliminate poverty within five year
deserves to
be reexamined.
December 10, 2008
Next: Chinese
Agriculture at a Crossroad |