THE
FOLLY OF INTERVENTION
By
Henry C.K. Liu
Part
1: The zero interest rate trap
Part II: No Exit for
Emergency Nationalization
The notion that
nationalization is only an emergency measure that can be undone as soon
as the
economy recovers appears to be wishful thinking.
Discussing the Fed’s market
exit strategy problem, Bernanke said in his London School of Economics
Stamp
Lecture: The Crisis and the Policy
Response:
Exit
Strategy
Some
observers have expressed the concern that, by expanding its balance
sheet,
the Federal Reserve is effectively printing money, an action that will
ultimately be inflationary. The Fed’s lending activities have indeed
resulted
in a large increase in the excess reserves held by banks. Bank
reserves,
together with currency, make up the narrowest definition of money, the
monetary
base; as you would expect, this measure of money has risen
significantly as the
Fed’s balance sheet has expanded. However, banks are choosing to leave
the
great bulk of their excess reserves idle, in most cases on deposit with
the
Fed. Consequently, the rates of growth of broader monetary aggregates,
such as
M1 and M2, have been much lower than that of the monetary base. At
this
point, with global economic activity weak and commodity prices at low
levels, we see little risk of inflation in the near
term; indeed, we expect inflation to continue to moderate.
In
other words, the Fed’s bank nationalization
measures had not helped the economy as banks had chosen not obey
government
intention to increase lending. These measures had very little, if any,
effect
on deflation which exacerbates the need of banks for recapitalization.
Bernanke went on:
However,
at some point, when credit markets
and the economy have begun to recover, the Federal Reserve will have to
unwind
its various lending programs. To some extent, this unwinding will
happen
automatically, as improvements in credit markets should reduce the need
to use
Fed facilities. Indeed, where possible we have tried to set lending
rates and
margins at levels that are likely to be increasingly unattractive to
borrowers
as financial conditions normalize. In addition, some programs–those
authorized
under the Federal Reserve’s so-called 13(3) authority, which requires a
finding
that conditions in financial markets are “unusual and exigent”–will by
law have
to be eliminated once credit market conditions substantially normalize.
However, as the unwinding of the Fed’s
various programs effectively constitutes a tightening of policy, the
principal
factor determining the timing and pace of that process will be the
Committee’s
assessment of the condition of credit markets and the prospects for the
economy.
In other words,
de-nationalization will prolong the recession. Since
nationalization of the financial sector had been necessary to save the
financial system from imploding, it was not a Keynesian move to
stimulate
economic recovery, all the misleading euphemism notwithstanding. What
the Fed
did was to keep the critically ill patient alive with extraordinary
measures,
even if the cost is a drawn out long-term recovery that requires
hospitalization for the rest of his life. Small government cannot be
restored
by big government, even temporarily. Also, near zero interest rates can
hardly
be described as “unattractive” to borrowers.
Bernanke went on to explain:
As
lending programs are scaled back, the
size of the Federal Reserve’s balance sheet will decline, implying a
reduction
in excess reserves and the monetary base. A significant
shrinking of the balance sheet can be accomplished
relatively quickly, as a substantial portion of the assets that the
Federal
Reserve holds–including loans to financial institutions, currency
swaps, and
purchases of commercial paper–are short-term in nature and can simply
be
allowed to run off as the various programs and facilities are scaled
back or
shut down. As the size of the balance sheet and the
quantity of
excess reserves in the system decline, the Federal Reserve will be able
to
return to its traditional means of making monetary policy–namely, by
setting a
target for the federal funds rate.
Although a large portion of Federal Reserve assets are
short-term in
nature, we do hold or expect to hold significant quantities of
longer-term
assets, such as the mortgage-backed securities that we will buy over
the next
two quarters. Although longer-term
securities can also be sold, of course, we would not anticipate
disposing of
more than a small portion of these assets in the near term, which will
slow the
rate at which our balance sheet can shrink. We are monitoring
the
maturity composition of our balance sheet closely and do not expect a
significant problem in reducing our balance sheet to the extent
necessary at
the appropriate time.
Importantly,
the management of the Federal Reserve’s balance sheet and
the conduct of monetary policy in the future will be made easier by the
recent
congressional action to give the Fed the authority to pay interest on
bank
reserves. In principle, the interest rate the Fed pays on bank reserves
should
set a floor on the overnight interest rate, as banks should be
unwilling to
lend reserves at a rate lower than they can receive from the Fed. In
practice,
the federal funds rate has fallen somewhat below the interest rate on
reserves
in recent months, reflecting the very high volume of excess reserves,
the
inexperience of banks with the new regime, and other factors. However, as excess reserves decline, financial
conditions normalize, and banks adapt to the new regime, we expect the
interest
rate paid on reserves to become an effective instrument for controlling
the
federal funds rate.
Moreover, other tools are available or can be developed to improve
control of the federal funds rate during the exit stage. For example,
the
Treasury could resume its recent practice of issuing supplementary
financing
bills and placing the funds with the Federal Reserve; the issuance of
these
bills effectively drains reserves from the banking system, improving
monetary
control. Longer-term assets can be financed through repurchase
agreements and
other methods, which also drain reserves from the system. In
considering
whether to create or expand its programs, the Federal Reserve will
carefully
weigh the implications for the exit strategy. And we will take all
necessary
actions to ensure that the unwinding of our programs is accomplished
smoothly
and in a timely way, consistent with meeting our obligation to foster
full
employment and price stability.”
The size of the Fed’s balance sheet cannot shrink unless fed funds rate
target remain near zero and fed funds rate target cannot rise above
near zero
until Fed balance sheet shrinks. Instead of price stability, Fed
actions has
created a stability of near zero interest rate and expanded Fed balance
sheet.
Fed balance sheet cannot shrink and zero interest rate also cannot rise
in the
foreseeable future. The repurchase
market, where the Fed Open Market Committee conducts its trading to
keep
the fed
funds rate on target, has been essentially halted by zero interest
rates.
Rescuing One Market
at a time
There are talks that some in
government are thinking of rescuing one
market at a time, such as the commercial paper market, by creating a
new bank
along the line of Hamilton’s First Bank of the United States to buy up
all
toxic assets, instead of “ring fencing” toxic asset one bank at a time.
The
objective is not to reduce the need for further write down, but to find
out
once and for all how deep the loss will turn out to be to stop the
continuing
loss of confidence. Until confidence is restored, private capital will
not
return to the market.
The Systemic Lesson
of the Lehman Bankruptcy
Since March 2008 the
Fed internally had in its possession the latest updated market
information. The
picture had been increasingly ominous, revealing effects a possible
Lehman
collapse would have on the precarious systemic interconnections and
cross-exposure to risk among investment banks, hedge funds and traders
in the
vast market for credit-default swaps and other derivative positions.
But in the
end, both potential private sector white knights to rescue Lehman and
the Fed’s
offer of aid blinked against Treasury’s ideological stare down against
any
pubic funds for a rescue of Lehman. After Lehman, the market knew that
the Fed
and the Treasury would no longer permit another bankruptcy if they
could help
it, assuming they could help it without bankrupting the government and
the
nation. Nationalization of the finance sector then became the only
realistic
option.
The
Lehman
bankruptcy on September 15,
2008 cut off all further private financing
for investment banks. Lending in the interbank deposit market dried up
as money
market funds shied away from providing banks with short-term loans
after
Lehman’s bankruptcy wiped out billions of dollars of its impaired debt.
Private
funds also pulled away from the commercial paper market, an important
source of
finance for industrial companies and non-bank financial firms.
That breakdown prompted the Fed to announce on October 7, 2008 the creation of the
Commercial Paper Funding Facility (CPFF), a facility that would
complement the
Fed’s existing credit facilities to help provide liquidity to term
funding
markets. The CPFF will provide a liquidity backstop to U.S.
issuers of commercial paper through a special
purpose vehicle (SPV) that will
purchase three-month unsecured and asset-backed commercial paper
directly from
eligible issuers. The Federal Reserve will provide financing to
the SPV
under the CPFF and such financing will be secured by all of the assets
of the
SPV and, in the case of commercial paper that is not asset-backed
commercial
paper, by the retention of up-front fees paid by the issuers or by
other forms
of security acceptable to the Federal Reserve in consultation with
market
participants. This essentially nationalized the commercial paper
market.
The Treasury believes this facility is necessary
to prevent
substantial disruptions to the financial markets and the economy and
will make
a special deposit at the Federal Reserve Bank of New
York
in support of this facility. Since the end of October, 2008, the
central bank
has purchased more than $313 billion in commercial paper alone. The Fed
has
also implemented a number of other liquidity programs designed to help
banks access
funds rather than rely on the private interbank market.
Most market participants expect the Fed’s
liquidity programs
to remain in place at least through 2009 and that it would be a
challenge for
the central bank to formulate a workable exit strategy from its support
of the
financial system. The freeze in lending was best tracked by watching a
surge in
floating money market rates. At the daily fixing in London,
the three-month dollar London Interbank Offered Rate (LIBOR) rose to a
peak of
4.82% in October 2008.
Since then the Fed’s provision of liquidity and
aggressive
rate cuts has been identified as having helped ease some of the strain
in LIBOR
but the real reason was a drop in interbank borrowing to keep demand
down. On January 9, 2009,
LIBOR was at 1.41%.
Strong demand for recently issued bank debt that is backed by the
Federal
Deposit Insurance Corp has also helped ease funding strains.
However, as of January 9, 2009, LIBOR still remained elevated
when compared with near zero
fed funds rate. With official overnight interest rates near zero,
problems
remain for the repurchase (repo) market, the other important source of
bank
funding,
and in which Fed open market actions trade to keep the fed funds rate
on target.
Fear of lending securities in exchange for a short-term cash loan
dominated the
repo market.
Zero Interest Rate
Stalls the Repo Market
The collapse of investment banks in 2008 showed
how
short-term funding is dependent on two factors. One is the federal
funds rate,
the interest rate at which depository institutions lend balances at the
Federal
Reserve to other depository institutions overnight. The other is the
government’s
participation in the repurchase or “repo” market.
Data reported by 19
primary dealers5 and around 1,000 bank holding
companies suggest that by mid-2008 the gross market capitalization of
the US
repo market exceeded $10 trillion (including double-counting of repos
and
reverse repos), corresponding to around 70% of US GDP.
Over the past decade, many banks also have
become dependent
on the repo market, whereby they lend out assets such as Treasuries,
top-rated mortgages
securities and other top-rated bonds in return for short-term cash. The
freeze
in repo financing helped bring down Bear Stearns as investors lost
confidence
over lending cash collateralized by Bear Stearns securities. Lehman’s
bankruptcy left investors questioning the creditworthiness of all
banks.
Consequently, the repo market seized.
While lending for overnight continues, term
repo, any
agreement with a lifespan of more than one day, remained impaired by
the fear
factor. The breakdown in the repo market also upset the trading of
interest
rate swaps as dealers often hedge the derivative with government paper.
The
cost of financing swaps in the repo market helps influence where swaps
trade
relative to Treasury yields.
Heightened volatility in daily LIBOR settings
made it
extremely difficult to trade swaps, which involves exchanging two cash
flows. One
flow is a fixed rate that is priced off Treasury yields, while the
floating rate
references three-month LIBOR. The problems in the repo market peaked in
October
2008 when failed trades rose to a record $5 trillion. A repo “fail”
occurs when
a security that was previously borrowed is not returned on time.
(Please see my April 2, 2008
AToL article: THE SHAPE OF US POPULISM, Part 4: A
panic-stricken
Federal Reserve)
Given the entrenched links between dealers and
investors,
once a security fails, it can ripple along a long chain and shut down
the repo
market, which was what happened in the aftermath of the Lehman
bankruptcy on September 15,
2008.
Although repo fails have since been cleaned up,
the repo
market faces renewed problems as the Fed’s infusion of liquidity has
lowered
the effective fed funds rate to nearly zero per cent. This interest
rate
environment negates the profit from lending out a Treasury security in
exchange
for a short-term cash loan.
The repo market will implement in May 2009 new
rules proposed
by the Treasury Market Practices Group (TMPG) which
comprises senior members of security
dealers, banks and investment firms who are involved in the repo market
and
endorsed by the Fed. The primary goal is to alleviate repo fails by
introducing
a penalty rate for dealing with failed securities. That will enable a
security
to trade at a negative level capped at 3% below current fed funds rate
targets
With official
rates now in a band between zero and 0.25 per cent, the cost of failing
to
deliver a borrowed Treasury is minimal and in such a climate, the
amount of
failed trades usually rises.
The TMPG said
in its release: “Since November, short-term interest rates have
declined to
unprecedented levels, increasing the urgency to implement new practices
to
enhance liquidity and improve functioning of the US Treasury market.”
The use of
repo is a crucial source of short term funding for financial firms as
they can
lend out their holdings of Treasuries and other securities as
collateral in
return for cash loans. Treasury traders and investors also value a
smoothly
functioning repo market as it allows them to sell bonds short by
borrowing them
from others.
Under the new
rules, a charge for failing to return a borrow security on time is
computed as
being 3% minus the lower end of the current Fed funds rate band, which
is zero
per cent. Once the penalty rate is enacted at the start of May, the
TMPG says
the first monthly submission of claims by repo participants is expected
on June
12, 2009.
As the repo market struggles to adjust to a new regime of
low and negative interest rates, and investors wait for signs that
money market
funds have started trusting banks again, there is no certainty that the
worst
is past. The wild card is another unanticipated shock to the system.
In the aftermath of the September 11, 2001 terrorist attacks,
by definition
‘unprecedented’ events, the Treasury moved on October 4, 2001 to hold an unscheduled
auction of
10-year Treasury notes in an effort to improve conditions in the repo
market.
The Treasury auctioned $6 billion more of the 5% 10-year note maturing
in
August 2011. The Treasury still sold 10-year notes as part of its
regularly
scheduled quarterly refunding in late October 2001. The Treasury acted
to
ameliorate risk triggered by a cascade of failed trades subsequent to
the
attacks of September 11, 2001.
The situation was exacerbated by several factors, including increased
demand
for Treasury securities, disrupted telecommunications, and the
reluctance of
repo market participants to enter into trades, particularly as the end
of the
third quarter 2001 passed, out of concern for the ability of the system
to
regain its smooth functioning. The ‘fails rate’, a measure of trades
that do
not settle, which typically ranges below $3 billion, had surged as high
as $40
billion by Q3, 2001.
The repo rate for general collateral that
prevailed before September
11, 2001 was typically
close to the federal funds rate, which was cut twice by 50 basis points
each after
the attacks. The first cut coming on September 17, before the halted
stock
market first reopened, and the second occurring on October 2, at the
Federal
Open Market Committee’s regular meeting. For the period immediately
after
September 11 and until the aforementioned October 4, 10-year note
reopening,
the “special” rate applying to the loan of both current 5 and 10-year
notes was
close to zero.
The repo market indirect
influences the Treasury market and, more broadly, all fixed-income
valuations
and new issuance. The Treasury market and by extension the repo market
is critical
for everything from determining mortgage rates to funding the federal
budget. The
panorama of recent events is a good reminder of the role liquidity
plays in the
portfolio management process. This is true not only within the Treasury
market,
but also beyond it, in the sister fixed-income markets.
The Treasury market relies on the two-way flows
of market
participants, both the buyers and sellers, the offer and the bid sides.
The
financing of forward settlements of Treasury securities is typically
accomplished in the repo market. On one side of the transaction, an
entity with
Treasuries on hand may chose to borrow money at a specified, often
below market
rate (repo rate), using the specified Treasuries as collateral. This is
known
as a Repurchase Agreement, or repo for short. Effectively, this
participant is
selling the Treasuries and repurchasing them at a later date, with the
forward
price being calculated using the special financing rate. On the other
side of
the transaction, an entity seeking to borrow those Treasuries will lend
money
at that same rate, effectively buying the Treasuries and selling them
back at a
later date (reverse repurchasing them or reverse repoing them). The
forward
price of the transaction is calculated using the aforementioned special
financing rate. Thus for one side the transaction is a borrowing, for
the other
a loan, accepting cash in exchange for securities, or securities in
exchange
for cash respectively.
A true repo transaction involves collateral
movement and
often requires a ‘haircut’, or additional collateral, typically 2%, to
be
posted for the loan. Also, the legal documentation for repurchase
transactions
is specific and details the rights to control of the collateral. There
are also
types of repo differentiated by who holds the collateral, and what
rights of
substitution, if any, apply. The following is a simplistic example of
the
economics of a repo transaction. Specifically, the analysis is actually
that of
a sell/buy back transaction, where the securities transactions are
entered into
with settlements occurring and ownership changing. This differs from a
true
repo where only journal entries are made as collateral is posted and
returned
and ownership does not change.
The repo market is affects how a
broader arena of securities is traded. In
the Treasury market, the most liquid
securities that trade among
dealers are typically the most recently issued benchmark Treasuries,
the 2, 5,
10 and to a lesser extent the 30 year notes and bonds. Dealers trade
these
against other Treasury securities that are mostly held in portfolios,
whether
for flow or positioning reasons. Dealers use their expertise in the
markets to
evaluate the differences among Treasuries as to coupon and maturity
(quantitative characteristics) as well as perceived availability,
demand and
other factors (more qualitative characteristics) so they may ultimately
price
them relative to the benchmarks. By extension, in sister fixed-income
markets
to the Treasury market, such as the agency, corporate, and
mortgage-Backed
securities markets, Treasury securities may also be used for the same
risk and
inventory management purposes. Given the size of these markets (the
Treasury
market alone is over $3 trillion), that the amount of activity in these
benchmarks is great. Other securities in addition to Treasury
benchmarks are
used in a similar manner, including benchmark agency and certain large
corporate
issues and current coupon mortgage-backed securities. Derivative
instruments,
such as futures on Treasury securities are also actively employed.
These in
aggregate create enormous liquidity but must ultimately to some extent
refer
back to the cash and repo market fundamentals in deriving their
valuations. There
is a multiplier effect stemming from the use of benchmark securities.
During
periods of crisis in the financial markets, particularly a crisis in
the
infrastructure of the Treasury market itself, there is an extreme focus
of both
demand for and concern about the primary, underlying securities that
represent
the source of the accumulated, multiplied liquidity in the system.
Whether or not a fixed-income portfolio manager
engages in
repo or reverse-repo transactions directly, there is a critical
indirect
relationship to the repo market that must be evaluated in a number of
term
structure, sector and security selection issues. Over the last several
years,
the Treasury benchmarks have been reduced from 2, 3, 4, 5, 7, 10 and
30-year
securities to 2, 5, 10 and 30-year securities. Some of this reflects
securities
that have simply stopped being issued, or issuance has dwindled
significantly,
as is the case with the 30-year. The
liquidity of these issues has become more concentrated, as the size of
the
Treasury market overall has been reduced and there is consolidation
amongst
market participants. Spreads of other securities to these benchmarks
have
generally widened over this period, to reflect the difference in
liquidity and
to reflect the economics of more favorable repo rates in benchmark
Treasuries
than elsewhere. The benchmark Treasuries
typically have lower yields than surrounding issues on the maturity
spectrum to
reflect this premium. Since Treasury issuance is itself managed to
promote
liquidity, the benchmark model would be incorporated in the sister
fixed-income
markets. The benchmark effect drives key rates on the term structure.
These key
rates in turn, act as fundamental valuation pillars for the different
fixed-income sectors, some of which have greater clarity to the term
structure
than others (bullet agency or corporate as opposed to variable cash
flow
Mortgage-Backed securities). Finally, the actions of key rates have a
great
deal of impact on security selection decisions, as maturity or duration
decisions are the most critical determinants of fixed-income total
return.
The repo market is very large and
pervasive, extending both directly and indirectly to the sister
fixed-income markets.
The key nexus for transmission from the repo markets is in the pricing
of
liquidity of the benchmark issues. The multiplier effects of liquidity
in the
system and the displacements that occur are substantial when either
systemic
de-leveraging or re-leveraging activities are conducted.
Impact on State and
Local Government Finance
State and local government finance departments
across the US
were hit with an abrupt spike in borrowing rates as the auction-rate
securities
(ARS) market, a $330 billion component of the municipal bond market,
collapsed
in February 2008. ARS are debt instruments issued by corporations or
municipalities with a long-term nominal maturity for which the interest
rate is
regularly reset through a Dutch auction. Ronald
Gallatin at Lehman Brothers invented
ARS in 1984 and Goldman
Sachs introduced the first auction rate security for the tax-exempt
market in
1988. Student loan auction rate securities (SLARS) make up a large
percentage
of the ARS market. (Please see my September 24 2008 AToL article: Developing China with sovereign credit
– section on
ARS fraud investigation.)
The $2 trillion public finance market where
state and local
entities raise money for roads, bridges, schools hospitals, airports
and even
prisons stopped functioning in early 2008. Traditionally, municipal
bonds were
a quiet and orderly segment of the financial markets. Returns were
predictably stable
and the investor base was mostly individual US
tax-exempt savers. The 50,000 odd issuers, though ranging from tiny
local fire
departments to the gigantic state of New York,
were standardized through insurance, giving the market a de facto
triple-A
rating. Municipal bonds as a group lost 7.6% in 2008, the worst year
ever for a
low-yield “save” investment vehicle. Auction-rate securities, which
normally had
been a source of low-cost funding for many issuers, have disappeared
from the
market. Long-term borrowing costs even for top-rated, triple-A
municipalities
have risen to nearly 6%, an eight-year high, and a backlog of more than
$100 billion
in postponed bond sales spilled into 2009.
Big municipal bond insurers, such as MBIA and
Ambac, also
had written similar policies on risky sub-prime mortgage debt. When the
mortgage market cracked, so did the monolines, prompting a massive
re-pricing
of municipal debt to the issuers’ underlying ratings. It also upset
financing
arrangements like auction rate securities. (Please see my June 26,
20008 AToL
article: THE ROAD TO HYPERINFLATION - Fed helpless in its own crisis)
At the same time, hedge funds, a growing group
of buyers of municipal
debt in recent years, became net sellers, unleashing huge supply on an
already
bruised muni market. The final straw that broke the market’s back came
with the
bankruptcy of Lehman Brothers, which drained liquidity abruptly from
the whole
financial system.
Lured by the high relative yields, some
adventurous retail
investors have stepped in, but not enough to sustain normal level of
issuance. The
market is expected to remain under pressure in 2009. With the economy
in a
recession, states and local governments are facing growing budget
deficits. The
federal government appears to favor stimulus for state and local
economies over
direct aid to state and local governments, Consequently the credit
derivatives
market is pricing in a greater risk of default for muni debts than for
high-grade corporate bonds.
Near zero short-term interest rates are sharply
corroding
the smooth functioning of the government repurchase (repo) market, a
foundation
stone for the financial system and trading Treasury debt.
While the Federal Reserve reduced its benchmark
interest
rate from 1% to a new range of zero to 0.25% on December 16, 2008, short-term market
rates have been
trading at close to zero per cent in recent weeks. Driven by a flight
to safety
by investors and expectations of rate cuts, such conditions are
creating
problems in the repo market, where investors borrow Treasuries in
return for
short-term cash loans.
Repo contracts allow traders to sell Treasuries
without
owning them in the first place, while owners of government debt can
fund their
portfolios by lending Treasuries.
A zero short-term rate reduces the financial incentive to
lending securities. The reduction in liquidity in the $5.8 trillion
Treasury
market is coming at a time when financial market conditions have become
strained. The problems also come as the US Treasury prepares to issue a
massive
amount of new government bonds for the current financial year to fund
expected
fiscal deficits. President-elect Barack Obama is warning the US
deficit will top $1 trillion in 2009.
The point is being reached where structural
damage caused by
near zero interest rates outweighs any benefit from monetary policy
easing
through interest rate cuts. In a financial environment where the
Treasury faces
an additional net financing need of over $1.8 trillion, low trading
volume caused
by near zero short-term rates is a major problem.
Problems in the repo market will impair general
trading
across the entire Treasury market. A rise in “failed” trades, where a
borrowed
security is not returned in time, becomes a drain on balance sheets of
dealers.
Near zero interest rates are also hampering the ability of dealers to
finance
positions by matching offsetting trades. The zero interest rate
environment is
effectively eliminating the dealer matched-book business and crippling
dealer
intermediation in the repo market.
The scarcity of Treasuries for
repos means that buying for repoing will
also lead Treasury prices to rise and yields to plummet. Since Treasury
bill
prices are used as the input into other pricing models (most notably
the
Black-Scholes option pricing model), the distortions in the Treasure
market
have the potential to feed into other markets.
Surging demand for US Treasuries is causing failures to deliver or
receive
government debt to climb to the highest level in almost four years in
the $6.3
trillion daily market for borrowing and lending. Failures, an
indication of
scarcity, surged to $1.795 trillion in the week ended March 5, 2008 the highest
since May 2004, and up from $374 billion the prior week. They have
averaged
$493.4 billion a week in 2009, compared with $359.6 billion over the
last five
years and $168.8 billion back through July 1990, according to Federal
Reserve
Bank of New York data.
Investors seeking the safety of government debt amid the loss of
confidence in
credit markets pushed rates on three-month bills down to 0.387% in
January 2009,
the lowest level since 1954.
The repo market is the biggest financial
market today. Domestic and
international repo markets have grown dramatically over the last few
years due
to increasing need by market participants to take and hedge short
positions in
the capital and derivatives markets; a growing concern over
counterparty credit
risk; and the favorable capital adequacy treatment given to repos by
the market.
Most important of all is a growing awareness among market participants
of the
flexibility of repos and the wide range of markets and circumstances in
which
they can benefit from using repos. The use of repos in financing and
leveraging
market positions and short-selling, as well as in enhancing returns and
mitigating risk, is indispensable for full participation in today’s
financial
markets.
Unless the repo market is disrupted by seizure, repos can be rolled
over easily
and indefinitely. What changes is the repo rate, not the availability
of funds.
If the repo rate rises above the rate of return of the security
financed by a
repo, the interest rate spread will turn negative against the borrower,
producing a cash-flow loss. Even if the long-term rate rises to keep
the
interest rate spread positive for the borrower, the market value of the
security will fall as long-term rate rises, producing a capital loss.
Because
of the interconnectivity of repo contracts, a systemic crisis can
quickly
surface from a break in any of the weak links within the market.
(Please see my September
29, 2005 AToL
article: The
Repo Time Bomb)
Repos are useful to central banks both as a monetary policy instrument
and as a
source of information on market expectations. Repos are attractive as a
monetary policy instrument because they carry a low credit risk while
serving
as a flexible instrument for liquidity management. In addition, they
can serve
as an effective mechanism for signaling the stance of monetary policy.
The secondary credit market is where Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac,
so-called GSEs
(government sponsored enterprises, or agencies) are traded. GSEs were
founded with
government help decades ago to make home ownership easier by purchasing
loans
that commercial lenders make, then either hold them in their portfolios
or
bundle them with other loans into mortgage-backed securities for sale
in the
credit market. Mortgage-backed securities are sold to mutual funds,
pension
funds, Wall Street firms and other financial investors who trade them
the same
way they trade Treasury securities and other bonds. Many
participants in
this market source their funds in the repo market.
In this mortgage market, investors, rather than banks, set mortgage
rates by
setting the repo rate. Whenever the economy is expanding faster than
the money
supply growth, investors demand higher yields from mortgage lenders.
However,
the Fed is a key participant in the repo market as it has unlimited
funds with
which to buy repo or reverse repo agreements to set the repo rate.
Investors
will be reluctant to buy low-yield bonds if the Fed is expected to
raise
short-term rates higher. Conversely, prices of high-yeild bonds will
rise
(therefore lowering yields) if the Fed is expected to lower short-term
rates.
In a rising-rate environment, usually when the economy is viewed by the
Fed as
overheating, securitized loans can only be sold in the credit market if
yields
also rise. The reverse happens when the economy slows. But since the
Fed can directly
affect only the repo rate directly, the long-term rate does not always
follow
the short-term rate because of a range of factors, such as a time-lag,
market
expectation of future Fed monetary policy and other macro events. This
divergence from historical correlation creates profit opportunities for
hedge
funds.
Investors buy bonds to lock in high yields if they expect the Fed to
cut
short-term rates in the future to stimulate the economy. When bond
investor
demand is strong, mortgage lenders can offer lower mortgage rates for
consumers
because high bond prices lead to lower bond yields. But lower
interest
rates leads to inflation which discourages bond investment. Lower
interest
rates also lower the exchange value of the dollar, allowing non-dollar
investors to bid up dollar asset prices. Non-dollar investors are not
necessarily foreigners. They are anyone with non-dollar revenue, such
as US
transnational companies that sell overseas or mutual funds that invest
in non-dollar
economies. Unlike investors, hedge funds do not buy bonds to hold, but
to
speculate on the effect of interest rate trends on bond prices by going
long or
short on bonds of different maturity, financed by repos.
As with other financial markets, repo markets are also subject to
credit risk,
operational risk and liquidity risk. However, what distinguishes the
credit
risk on repos from that associated with uncollateralized instruments is
that
repo credit exposures arise from volatility (or market risk) in the
value of
collateral. For example, a decline in the price of securities serving
as
collateral can result in an under-collateralization of the repo.
Liquidity risk
arises from the possibility that a loss of liquidity in collateralized
markets
will force liquidation of collateral at a discount in the event of a
counterparty default, or even a fire sale in the event of systemic
panic.
Leverage that is built up using repos can exponentially increase these
risks
when the market turns. While leverage facilitates the efficient
operation of
financial markets, rigorous risk management by market participants
using
leverage is important to maintain these risks at prudent levels. In
general,
the art of risk management has been trailing the decline of risk
aversion.
Up to a point, repo markets have offsetting effects on systemic risk.
They can
be more resilient than uncollateralized markets to shocks that increase
uncertainty about the credit standing of counterparties, limiting the
transmission of shocks. However, this benefit can be neutralized by the
fact
that the use of collateral in repos withdraws securities from the pool
of
assets that would otherwise be available to unsecured creditors in the
event of
a bankruptcy. Another concern is that the close linkage of repo markets
to
securities markets means they can transmit shocks originating from this
source.
Finally, repos allow institutions to use leverage to take larger
positions in
financial markets, which adds to systemic risk.
The Repo Market now Big and Dangerous
Created to raise funds to pay for the flood of
securities sold by the US
government to finance growing budget deficits in the 1970's, the repo
market
has grown into the largest financial market in the world, surpassing
stocks,
bonds, and even foreign-exchange.
At a time around 1998 when the world’s biggest government bond market
was
shrinking because of a temporary US
fiscal surplus, the market where investors financed their long bond
purchases
with short-term loans continued to grow by leaps and bounds. The
$2
trillion daily repo market in 1998 became the place where bond firms
and
investors raise cash to buy securities, and where corporations and
money market
funds park trillions of electronic dollars daily to lock in risk-free
attractive returns. That market has since grown to over $5 trillion a
day,
almost 50% of GDP.
The repo market grew exponentially as it came to be used to raise
short-term
money at lower rates for financing long-term investments such as bonds
and
equities with higher returns. The derivatives markets also require a
thriving
financing market, and repos are an easy way to raise low-interest funds
to pay
for securities needed for arbitrage plays. It used to be that the
purchase of securities could not be financed by repos, but those
restrictions
have long been relaxed along with finance deregulation. Repos were used
first
to raise money to finance only government bonds, then corporate bonds
and later
to finance equities. The risk of such financing plays lies in the
unexpected sudden
rise in short-term rates above the fixed returns of long-term assets.
For
equities, rising short-term rates can directly push equity prices
drastically
down, reflecting the effect of interest rates on corporate profits.
Hard figures on the size of the repo market in the US
or Europe are not easy to come by. The Bond
Market
Association, a trade group representing US
bond dealers, provides estimates of US
market size based on surveys taken by the New York Federal Reserve Bank
on
daily financing transactions made by its primary dealers that do
business
directly with the Fed. By Fed statistics, the US
repo market command average trading volume of about $5 trillion per day
in
2004, up from $2 trillion in 1998, and the European one now passed 5
trillion
euros in outstandings. Both have been growing at double-digit pace.
That jump
occurred even as the face value of US government bonds outstanding
declined to
$3.3 trillion from $3.5 trillion between 1999 and 1997 -- the first
drop since
the Treasury began selling 30-year bonds regularly in 1977. Total
Federal
government debt outstanding at the end of 2004 was $7.6 trillion,
nearly 70% of
GDP. In its February 2, 2005 Report to the Secretary of the
Treasury, the
Bond Market Association Treasury Borrowing Advisory Committee notes
that the
stock of Treasury debt currently held by foreigners is just over 50%,
and that
“with higher short rates would come greater risks of chronic or
intractable
fails if foreign participation in repo markets was not assured.”
The St
Louis Fed reports that as of September
30, 2008, Federal debt held by foreigners amounted to over
$2.86
trillion, about 18% of GDP.
The runaway repo market is another indication that the Fed is
increasingly
operating to support a speculative money market rather than following a
monetary policy ordained by the Full Employment and Balanced Growth Act
of
1978, known as the Humphrey-Hawkins Act. Under the Federal
Reserve Act as
amended by Humphrey-Hawkins, the Federal Reserve and the Fed Open
Market Committee
(FOMC) are charged with the job of seeking “to promote effectively the
goals of
maximum employment, stable prices, and moderate long-term interest
rates.”
Humphrey-Hawkins mandates that, in the pursuit of these goals,
the
Federal Reserve and the FOMC establish annual objectives for growth in
money
and credit, taking account of past and prospective economic
developments to
support full employment. The act introduces the term "full
employment" as a policy goal, although the content of the bill had been
watered down before passage by snake-oil economics to consider 4%
unemployment
as structural. Unemployment near or below the structural level is
deemed
structurally inconsistent due to its impact on inflation (causing wages
to
rise! - a big no-no for die-hard monetarists), thus only increasing
unemployment down the road. Structural unemployment is now
theoretically set at
6%.
Unfortunately, aside from being morally offensive, this definition of
full
employment is not even good economics. It distorts real deflation as
nominal
low inflation and widens the gap between nominal interest rate and real
interest rate, allowing demand constantly to fall behind supply.
Humphrey-Hawkins has been described as the last legislative gasp of
Keynesianism’s doomed effort by liberal senator Hubert Humphrey to
refocus on
an official policy against unemployment. Alas, most of the progressive
content
of the law had been thoroughly vacated even before passage. Full
employment has
not been a national policy for the US
since the New Deal. Yet few have bothered to ask what kind of economic
system
is it that the richest country in the world cannot afford employment
for all
its citizens.
The one substantive reform provision: requiring the Fed to make public
its
annual target range for growth in the three monetary aggregates: the
three Ms,
namely M1 = currency in circulation, commercial bank demand deposits,
NOW
(negotiable order of withdrawal) and ATS (auto transfer from savings),
credit-union share drafts, mutual-savings-bank demand deposits,
non-bank
traveler's checks; M2 = M1 plus overnight repurchase agreements issued
by
commercial banks, overnight eurodollars, savings accounts, time
deposits under
$100,000, money market mutual shares; and M3 = M2 plus time deposits
over
$100,000 and term repo agreements. A fourth category, known a L,
measures M3
plus all other liquid assets such as Treasury bills, savings bonds,
commercial
paper, bankers’ acceptances and Eurodollar holdings of US residents
(non-bank). Changes in the financial system, particularly since
the
deregulation of banking and financial markets in the 1980s, have
contributed to
controversy among economists about the precise definition of the money
supply.
M1, M2 and M3 now measure money and near-money while L measures
long-term liquid
funds. There is no agreement on the amount of L. The controversy
is
further complicated by the financing of long-term instruments with
short-term
repos which while being a money creation venue, can be mercuric in
outstanding
volume.
The persistent expansion in the money supply has been accompanied by a
decline
in the efficiency of money to generate GDP. In 1981, two dollars in the
money
supply (M3 - $2 trillion) yielded three dollars of GDP ($3 trillion), a
ratio
of two to three. In 2005, ten dollars in the money supply (M3 – $10
trillion)
yields twelve dollars of GDP ($12 trillion), a ratio of two-and-a-half
to
three. It now takes 25% more money to produce the same GDP than 25
years
ago. That 25% is the unproductiveness of debt that has infested
the economy,
not even counting the unknown quantity of virtual money that structured
finance
creates.
In 2000, when the Humphrey-Hawkins legislation requiring the Fed to set
target
ranges for money-supply growth expired, the Fed announced that it was
no longer
setting such targets, because it no longer considered money-supply
growth as
providing a useful benchmark for the conduct of monetary policy. It is
a
reasonable position since no one knows what the money supply and its
growth
rate really are. However, the Fed said that “the FOMC believes that the
behavior of money and credit will continue to have value for gauging
economic
and financial conditions. Moreover, M2, adjusted for changes in the
price
level, remains a component of the Index of Leading Indicators, which
some
market analysts use to forecast economic recessions and
recoveries.”
Non-useful data yield non-useful forecasts.
Money market funds, an increasingly popular
place to park
cash, will need to raise fees or close to new money to remain
profitable as
yields hover at near-zero, according to industry managers.
The funds, which manage $3.8 trillion and have
seen big cash
inflows, are reeling from frozen credit markets, subprime exposure and
a crisis
of confidence triggered by “breaking the buck”, or returning investors
less
than they paid in. The cost of running money market funds is greater
than the
fees charged. Usually, the difference is not great, and the funds are
able to
pick up profit on excess yield. However, the gap between costs and fees
has
widened, and yields have plummeted. The average yield on a Treasury
retail fund
was 0.34% at the end of November 2008, compared with 2.9% in December
2007.
About one in 10 money funds yields nothing. The Fed appeared to be
trying to
force investors out of a low-risk environment.
The overview picture is discouraging. Those in
whose hands
we entrust to restore health to the global financial system appear to
have no
clear view of how to correct the mess our global financial system has
evolved
into except jumping from crisis to crisis to keep the overly complex
structure
from collapsing. So far each move to respond to a crisis has only led
to
another crisis. The distressing part is that there seems to be a
complacent
view that nationalization is the panacea for when all else fails. We
should
realize that nations too can go bankrupt, even nations who were once
superpowers.
January 22, 2009 |